02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Internet Connection

WHAT WE CONSUME

The Bureau of Labor Statistics conducts regular surveys to

discover what households spend their income on. Information

from these Consumer Expenditure Surveys is available at

www.bls.gov/cex/home.htm. If you follow the link to “Consumer

Expenditures Annual Reports,” you will discover that the average

expenditure of the households surveyed in 2002 was $40,677,

of which 7.6 percent was spent on food at home, 5.1 percent on

food away from home, 32.7 percent on housing, and 1.0 percent

on public transportation. How do your expenditures compare

to those of a typical American household?

A Closer Look at the Demand

Curve

In Chapter 3, we saw the principal characteristic of the demand curve: when prices

rise, the quantity of a good demanded normally falls. Here, we take a closer look at

why. Doing so will help us understand why some goods respond more strongly to

price changes, that is, have a greater price elasticity.

Let us return to our earlier example of Fran buying CDs, shown in Figure 5.2. If

the price of CDs rises from $15 to $20, Fran will face a new budget constraint. If she

buys no CDs, she will still have $300 to spend on other goods; but if she decides to

spend all of her income on CDs, she can buy only 15 rather than 20. Figure 5.5 shows

Fran’s original budget constraint in light green and her new budget constraint in

dark green.

The increase in the price of CDs has one obvious and important effect: Fran

cannot continue to buy the same number of CDs and the same amount of other

goods as she did before. Earlier, Fran bought 11 CDs. If she again buys the same

number of CDs, it will cost her $55 more, and she will have $55 less to spend on other

goods. No matter what she does, Fran is worse off as a result of the price increase.

It is as if she had less income to spend. When she has less income to spend, she

reduces her expenditure on each good, including CDs. This part of the response to

the higher price is called the income effect. An increase in income of about $55, or

18 percent ($55 out of $300), would offset the price increase. 2 Assume the income elasticity

is approximately 1; that is, with income reduced by 18 percent, she would reduce

purchases of CDs by 18 percent, which is about 2 CDs. This part of the reduction of

the demand of CDs, from 11 to 9, is the income effect.

The magnitude of the income effect depends on two factors: how important the

commodity is to the individual—that is, how large a fraction of the individual’s income

2 Actually, it would slightly overcompensate. With the $55 increase, Fran could buy exactly the same bundle of

goods as before, but as we will soon see, she will choose to reallocate her spending. The reallocation will make

her better off.

300

OTHER GOODS ($)

Figure 5.5

CDs

15 20

EFFECT OF PRICE INCREASE

An increase in the price of CDs moves the

budget constraint down as shown. Fran

must cut back on the consumption of

some goods. Here, using the black dots

to mark her consumption points, we show

her cutting back on the consumption of

both CDs and other goods.

A CLOSER LOOK AT THE DEMAND CURVE ∂ 109

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!