02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

THE MARKET FOR HEALTH INSURANCE

The market for health insurance provides an illustration of the impact imperfect

information can have. It is estimated that about 45 million Americans are without

health insurance, and even those with insurance often feel dissatisfied with their

coverage. Understanding the problems with health care and the policy debates that

these problems have generated requires an understanding of the market for health

insurance, a market in which information, or rather the lack of information, plays a

major role.

The United States spends a larger fraction of its national income on health care

than most other developed countries, but its figures for life expectancy are lower and

for infant mortality are higher. Information problems and associated market failures

are a large part of the reason. Moral hazard—the reduced incentive to economize on

health care expenditures when a large fraction of the tab is picked up by insurance

firms—is one source of market failure. Adverse selection—the attempt of each insurance

firm to take the lowest-risk applicants, leaving those with high medical costs to

others—is another. In some countries, the first of these problems is addressed by

rationing the availability of health care and the second is overcome by having a

universal health care system that covers everyone, not just those at low risk.

In the standard model, consumers are assumed to be well-informed. But consumers

go to the doctor for information, to find out what is wrong with them.

Moreover, they typically must rely on the doctor’s advice. Economists worry that

under a fee-for-service system, in which doctors are paid for each of the services

they perform, there is an incentive to provide excessive care. Excessive here means

the marginal cost exceeds the marginal benefit to the patient. Making sure that

health care dollars are used efficiently requires that the marginal benefits of a particular

treatment, prescription, or procedure are balanced against the marginal

costs. Consumers can be expected to balance marginal benefits and costs when

they purchase most goods, but health care differs because consumers may lack the

information needed to assess the potential benefits of care and because those with

insurance typically bear only a small fraction of the marginal costs.

Today, more and more doctors work in “managed care” organizations, or HMOs,

where they are paid a flat fee up front. They then provide whatever care is needed

and receive no extra income from doing extra procedures. On average, doctors working

in managed care charge less and perform fewer surgeries, with no noticeable

effect on patient health. Critics worry that under managed care, doctors have an

incentive to underprovide services, since they receive no compensation at all for

providing care at the margin. Newspaper accounts of managed care programs denying

patients treatment have galvanized legislators to enact a patients’ bill of rights.

But while admitting that there may be occasional abuses, advocates argue that any

managed care organization guilty of repeated abuses would lose its patients.

Reputations can provide effective discipline. When employers provide a level playing

field between fee-for-service and managed care plans—contributing an equal

amount for each and making employees pay for the extra costs if they choose the

more expensive fee-for-service plans—more than half their employees, on average,

choose the managed care plan. Evidently, the employees do not feel that the benefits

of the extra services provided under fee-for-service are worth the extra cost.

340 ∂ CHAPTER 15 IMPERFECT INFORMATION IN THE PRODUCT MARKET

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!