02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

“standard” workweek—the 40-hour week that has become the 35-hour week—

respond over time to the attitudes (preferences) of workers.

We now apply the analysis of Chapter 5 to an individual’s choice between work

and leisure. Figure 8.1 shows the budget constraint of Steve, who earns an hourly

wage of $7. Accordingly, for each hour less of leisure Steve enjoys—for each extra hour

he works—he earns $7 more. That is, his consumption increases by $7. Underlying

this budget constraint is his time constraint. He has only so many hours a day, say

16, to spend either working or at leisure. For each extra hour he works, he has 1 less

hour of leisure. If he works 1 hour, his income is $7; if he works 2 hours, his income

is $14; and so forth. If he works 16 hours—he has no leisure—his income is $7 × 16 =

$112. The trade-off between income and leisure given by his budget constraint is

$7 per hour.

Steve will choose a point on the budget constraint according to his own preferences,

just as a consumer chooses between two goods (see Chapter 5). Let’s suppose that

he chooses point E 0 . At E 0 he has 10 hours of leisure, which means that he works

6 hours out of the total available time of 16 hours. His income is $42 per day.

In deciding which of the points along the budget constraint to choose, Steve

balances the marginal benefits of what he can buy with an additional hour’s wage

against the marginal costs—the value of the hour’s worth of leisure that he will have

to forgo. Steve and his brother, Jim, assess the marginal benefits and marginal costs

differently. Steve chooses point E 0 , while his brother chooses point E 1 . Jim values

the material things in life more and leisure less.

For Steve, at E 0 , the marginal benefit of the extra concert tickets or

other goods he can buy with the money he earns from working an extra

hour just offsets the marginal costs of that hour—the extra leisure he has

to give up. At points to the left of E 0 , Steve has less leisure (so the marginal

value of leisure is greater) and he has more goods (so the marginal value of

the extra goods he can get is lower). The marginal benefit of working less

exceeds the marginal costs, and so he works less—he moves toward point

E 0 . The converse arguments apply to Steve’s thinking about points to the

right of E 0 .

We can apply the same kind of reasoning to see why the workaholic Jim

chooses a point to the left of E 0 . At E 0 , Jim values goods more and leisure

less. The marginal benefit of working more exceeds the marginal costs. At

E 1 , the marginal benefit of working an extra hour (the extra consumption)

just offsets the marginal costs.

We can use this framework to derive a labor supply curve that shows the

quantity of labor supplied at different wages. Changes in wages have both

an income effect and a substitution effect. An increase in wages makes individuals

better off. When individuals are better off, they purchase more of

all goods. One of the “goods” they will want more of is leisure, so they work

less. This is the income effect. But an increase in wages also changes the

trade-offs. By giving up one more hour of leisure, the individual can get

more goods. Because of this, individuals are willing to work more. This is

the substitution effect.

When we looked at the case of a typical good in Chapter 5, we saw that

the income and substitution effects reinforce each other. A higher price

CONSUMPTION ($)

112

42

14

7

0

E 1

FIGURE 8.1

Steve’s

leisure time

Jim’s choice

Budget constraint

–Slope = 7

10

E 0

LEISURE (HOURS)

Steve’s choice

14 15 16

Steve’s

labor time

A BUDGET CONSTRAINT BETWEEN

LEISURE AND INCOME

Individuals are willing to trade leisure for an increase

in income, and thus in consumption. The budget

constraint shows Steve choosing E 0 , with 10 hours

of daily leisure, 6 hours of work, and $42 in daily

wages.

THE LABOR SUPPLY DECISION ∂ 177

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!