02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Normally, demand curves are downward sloping. As the price is lowered, consumers

are better off and so consume more of the good (the income effect); and the

lower relative price induces a further increase in consumption (the substitution effect).

Utility and the Description of

Preferences

We have seen that people choose a point along their budget constraint by weighing

the benefits of consuming more of one good against the costs—what they have to

forgo of other goods. Economists refer to the benefits of consumption as the utility

that individuals get from the combination of goods they consume. Presumably a

person can tell you whether or not he prefers a certain combination of goods to

another. Economists say that the preferred bundle of goods gives that individual a

higher level of utility than the other bundle of goods he could have chosen. Similarly,

economists say that the individual will choose the bundle of goods—within the budget

constraint—that maximizes his utility.

In the nineteenth century, social scientists, including the British philosopher

Jeremy Bentham, hoped that science would someday develop a machine that could

actually measure utility. A scientist could simply hook up some electrodes to an individual’s

head and read off a unique measure of “happiness.” Modern economists

have several useful ways of measuring changes in how well-off a person is.

For our purposes, one simple approach will suffice: we ask how much an individual

would be willing to pay to be in one situation rather than another. For example,

if Joe likes chocolate ice cream more than vanilla, it stands to reason that he

would be willing to pay more for a scoop of chocolate ice cream than for a scoop of

vanilla. Or if Diane would rather live in California than in New Jersey, it stands to

reason that she would be willing to pay more for the West Coast location.

Note that how much a person is willing to pay tells us nothing about the price

actually paid. What Joe has to pay for chocolate ice cream depends on market prices;

what he is willing to pay reflects his preferences. Willingness to pay is a useful measure

of utility, often helpful for purposes such as thinking about how individuals

allocate income along budget constraints. But the hopes of nineteenth-century economists,

that we could find some way of measuring utility that would enable us to

compare how much utility Fran got from a bundle of goods with how much utility Gary

obtained, are now viewed as pipe dreams.

Using willingness to pay as our measure of utility, we can construct a diagram like

Figure 5.7A, which shows the level of utility Mary receives from sweatshirts as the

number of sweatshirts she buys increases. This information is also given in Table 5.1.

Here we assume that Mary is willing to pay $400 for 5 sweatshirts, $456 for

6 sweatshirts, $508 for 7 sweatshirts, and so on. 3 Thus, 5 sweatshirts give her a

3 If these dollar amounts seem high relative to typical market prices, keep in mind that they reflect Mary’s willingness

to pay for sweatshirts, which is our measure of the utility she derives from them. Market prices may

be lower.

UTILITY AND THE DESCRIPTION OF PREFERENCES ∂ 113

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!