02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

we need to hold. Money we do not need for transactions is better used to purchase

financial assets that earn interest. Increases in the dollar value of transactions

increase the demand for money; decreases in the dollar value of transactions decrease

the demand for money.

A useful simplifying assumption is that the amount of money individuals hold

is proportional to the dollar value, or nominal value, of their income. The same will

be true when we aggregate the economy; the overall demand for money will be proportional

to aggregate nominal income, which we measure by GDP. As we learned

in Chapter 22, we can express GDP as PY, the price level (P ) times the real GDP

(Y ). If nominal income in the economy rises, people hold, on average, more money.

Nominal income can rise because of an increase either in real incomes or in the

price level. If their real incomes rise, people will typically hold more money on average,

since they are likely to increase consumption and thus engage in more transactions.

Money demand also rises if the general level of prices rise, even if real

income remains constant, because each transaction will involve more dollars. When

every cup of coffee costs, say, $3 rather than $2.50, it takes $30 rather than $25 to

fill up a tank of gasoline, and the bill for a trip to the grocery store is $60 rather

than $50, individuals, on average, will need to hold more money to carry out their

transactions.

Velocity The relationship between the aggregate demand for money and aggregate

nominal income can be represented by the quantity equation of exchange,

which defines the amount of money that individuals wish to hold as proportional to

nominal GDP. We can write this equation as

MV = PY,

where M is the quantity of money demanded and PY is the nominal GDP. The final

term in the equation is the factor of proportionality or velocity, V. Suppose, for

example, that each individual in the economy held enough money to pay for one

month’s worth of spending. In this case, velocity for each individual would equal 12—

annual expenditures would be twelve times the average level of money held. If an

individual’s annual income was $60,000, on average he would want to hold $5,000.

If velocity were 26, so that on average individuals held an amount of money equal

to only two weeks’ worth of expenditures, someone with an annual income of $60,000

would hold $2,308. When we add up all the individuals in the economy, velocity

enables us to predict the aggregate demand for money when the aggregate income

is known. For example, suppose GDP is $11.2 trillion per year and velocity is 26. Then

the demand for money will be $11.2 trillion divided by 26, or $43 billion. Velocity,

therefore, is a measure of how many times a given dollar gets spent over the course

of a year. The higher the value of velocity, the more times a dollar is spent—the faster

it speeds from one transaction to another.

Velocity will depend on the methods available in the economy for carrying out

transactions. If many purchases are made with money, V is larger than if money is

rarely used in making transactions. If innovations in the financial industry reduce

the average amount of money that individuals need to hold, velocity rises.

608 ∂ CHAPTER 28 MONEY, THE PRICE LEVEL, AND THE FEDERAL RESERVE

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!