02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

PRICE (p)

p* + t

p*

Figure 19.4

Q s

EFFECT OF TARIFFS

Q s

'

Imports

after

tariff

Q'

c

Initial

imports

Supply

curve

QUANTITY (Q )

Q c

Demand

curve

A small country faces a horizontal supply curve for a good at

the international price, p*. In the absence of tariffs, the price

in the country will be p*. The country will produce Q s (the

quantity along the supply curve corresponding to p*), consume

Q c (the quantity along the demand curve corresponding

to p*), and import Q c – Q s . A tariff at the rate t increases the

price in the country to p*+ t, lowers aggregate consumption

to Q’ c (the quantity along the demand curve corresponding to

p*+ t), and increases domestic production to Q’ s (the quantity

along the supply curve corresponding to p* + t). Domestic

producers are better off, but consumers are worse off.

Opponents of free trade are not swayed by these arguments,

but instead stress the costs to workers and communities as particular

industries shrink in response to foreign imports. The textile

worker in North Carolina who loses his job as a result of imports of

inexpensive clothing from China cannot instantly convert himself

into a computer programmer in California or an aircraft engineer

working for Boeing. But the fact is that jobs are being destroyed

and created all the time, irrespective of trade. Over the long run, the

increased demand for computer programmers and aircraft engineers

leads to higher salaries for those workers, thereby strengthening

the incentives for young workers to gain the skills needed for

these jobs and for others to relocate to areas where new jobs are

being created. The declining demand for textile workers lowers

salaries for textile workers, reducing the incentives for workers

to remain in that industry. The United States is characterized by

a high degree of labor mobility, and as jobs are created in one

part of the country and disappear in other parts, individuals and

families often move to seek new employment opportunities.

On balance, the country benefits from these changes, but the

benefits are not distributed evenly. The unemployed textile worker

sees only the economic hardship she faces and the cost of free trade.

For this reason, many economists argue that policies must be implemented

to help retrain and relocate workers displaced by trade so

that they too can share in the benefits that accrue from international

interdependence. To the extent that such assistance increases

the number of winners, it should reduce opposition to trade.

While the perceived costs of economic interdependence cannot

be ignored—especially when they become the subject of heated

political debate—the consensus among the vast majority of economists

is that the country as a whole benefits from freer trade.

We can summarize this central tenet as follows: There are gains from voluntary

exchanges. Whether it occurs between individuals or across national borders, voluntary

exchange can benefit all. Trade enables parties to specialize in activities in which

they have a comparative advantage.

Trade Policies

In spite of the gains from trade, countries have imposed a variety of barriers to it.

In the remainder of this chapter, we explore some of the common trade barriers and

the major initiatives to remove them.

COMMERCIAL POLICY

Countries that have no barriers to trade are said to practice free trade, but most

countries engage in some form of protectionism—that is, in one way or another they

434 ∂ CHAPTER 19 INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND TRADE POLICY

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!