02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Today, a slight rise in the unemployment rate brings demands for the government

to do something to “get the economy moving again.” And for good reason: In

today’s economy, when an extra 1 percent of the labor force becomes unemployed,

incomes in the economy fall by about $160 billion. A commitment to maintaining

full employment was absent in the 1930s, or at least there was much less agreement

over whether the government could (as well as whether it should) stimulate the

economy.

GETTING THE COUNTRY MOVING AGAIN

The attempts by government to pursue the goals established by the Employment

Act have helped economists learn about how the economy operates.

The 1960s saw the first active use of government policy to try to reduce overall

unemployment. During the 1960 presidential election, John F. Kennedy narrowly

defeated Richard Nixon in what had been the closest presidential race in U.S. history

until the contest between George W. Bush and Al Gore in 2000. In part, Nixon’s

defeat was due to the slowdown in economic activity and rise in unemployment that

the country experienced in 1959. During the six years from 1958 through 1963, the

unemployment rate averaged almost 6 percent; ten years before it had been 2.8 percent.

Kennedy’s Council of Economic Advisors proposed a policy based on the ideas

of John Maynard Keynes that was designed to stimulate the economy and bring the

unemployment rate down to 4 percent, a level that at the time was believed to be

consistent with “full employment.” The policy called for a major tax cut. Those who

opposed the cut argued that it would be fiscally irresponsible and lead to a deficit,

with the government spending more than it received in taxes. They contended that

inflation would rise and the cost of lower unemployment would be higher inflation.

The government would need to decide how much inflation it was willing to tolerate

to get unemployment down.

In what is perhaps the most famous macroeconomic policy experiment, the federal

government did cut taxes in 1964. At the same time, federal government expenditures

rose because of the Vietnam War and President Lyndon Johnson’s War on

Poverty programs. The unemployment rate did subsequently fall; in fact, it fell below

4 percent, reaching as low as 3.5 percent by 1969. Unfortunately, this fall in unemployment

was accompanied by rising inflation; the general level of prices in the United

States rose by only 1 percent in 1963, but by 1969 prices were rising at an annual

rate of 6.2 percent. To some extent, policymakers at the time thought that higher

inflation was simply the price they had to pay to maintain lower unemployment.

They saw this as a trade-off: lower unemployment required accepting higher inflation,

but inflation could always be reduced again, they believed, by letting average

unemployment return to the levels of the late 1950s and early 1960s.

STAGFLATION

During the 1970s, policymakers discovered that the trade-off between unemployment

and inflation they thought they were facing had somehow disappeared. Instead,

THE COMMITMENT TO FULL EMPLOYMENT AND GROWTH ∂ 477

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!