02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

and still be better off. However, these side payments are also illegal, and thus must

be subtle and hard to detect if they occur at all. While perfect coordination is seldom

possible, some industries have found a partial solution by allowing one firm to play

the role of the price leader. In the airline industry, American Airlines for a long time

acted as a price leader. As it increased or decreased prices, others followed suit.

Using Game Theory to Model Collusion Economists apply a branch of

mathematics called game theory to study collusion among oligopolists. Its basic

aim is to shed light on strategic choices—that is, on how people or organizations

behave when they expect their actions to influence the behavior of others. For

instance, when executives at a major airline decide to change fares for flights on a

certain route, they have to consider how their competitors might respond to the

price change. And the competitors, when deciding how to respond, have to consider

how the first airline might answer in turn. These are strategic decisions, just like

those typical of players in various sorts of games, such as chess, football, or poker.

Using game theory, the economist views the participants in a given situation as

players in a game, whose rules define certain moves. The outcomes of the game—

what each participant receives—are referred to as its payoffs, and they depend

on what each player does. Each participant in the game chooses a strategy; he decides

what moves to make. In games in which each player has the chance to make more

than one move (there is more than one round, or period), moves can depend on what

has happened in previous periods. Game theory begins with the assumption that

each player in the game is rational and knows that her rival is rational. Each is trying

to maximize his own payoff. The theory then tries to predict what each player will

do. The actions depend on the rules of the game and the payoffs.

One example of such a game is called the prisoner’s dilemma. Two prisoners, A

and B, alleged to be conspirators in a crime, are put into separate rooms. A police

officer goes into each room and makes a little speech: “Now here’s the

situation. If your partner confesses and you remain silent, you’ll get

five years in prison. But if your partner confesses and you confess

also, you’ll only get three years. On the other hand, perhaps your partner

remains silent. If you’re quiet also, we can send you to prison for

only one year. But if your partner remains silent and you confess, we’ll

let you out in three months. So if your partner confesses, you are

better off confessing, and if your partner doesn’t confess, you

are better off confessing. Why not confess?” This deal is offered to

both prisoners.

Figure 12.9 shows the results of this deal. The upper left box, for

example, shows the result if both A and B confess. The upper right

box shows the result if prisoner A confesses but prisoner B remains

silent. And so on.

From the combined standpoint of the two prisoners, the best

option is clearly that they both remain silent and each serves one

year. But the self-interest of each individual prisoner says that confession

is best, whether his partner confesses or not. However, if

they both follow their self-interest and confess, they both end up

Prisoner

A

Figure 12.9

Confesses

Remains

silent

Confesses

A gets

3 years

Prisoner B

B gets

3 years

B gets

3 months

A gets

5 years

THE PRISONER’S DILEMMA

Remains silent

B gets

5 years

A gets

3 months

A gets

1 year

B gets

1 year

Both prisoners would be better off if both remained silent,

but their individual incentives lead each one to confess.

From the standpoint of prisoner A, confessing is the better

strategy if prisoner B confesses, and confessing is the better

strategy if prisoner B remains silent. The same holds for

prisoner B.

OLIGOPOLIES ∂ 277

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!