02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Wrap-Up

INFLATION AND CYCLICAL UNEMPLOYMENT

The natural rate of unemployment is the unemployment rate when the economy is at

potential GDP and cyclical unemployment is zero.

The short-run inflation adjustment (SRIA) curve shows the rate of inflation at each

level of output relative to potential GDP, for a given expected rate of inflation.

The SRIA curve has a positive slope. If output increases above potential, inflation

increases. If output falls below potential, inflation falls.

THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS: SHIFTS IN THE

SHORT-RUN INFLATION ADJUSTMENT CURVE

Figure 37.4 illustrated a second characteristic of the relationship between unemployment

and inflation—the relationship does not seem to be stable. It has shifted

over time. Though the relationship between cyclical unemployment and inflation

was stable in the 1960s, that stability disappeared in the 1970s. The U.S. economy experienced

high unemployment and high inflation. Stagflation was the term coined to

describe this undesirable situation. High inflation occurred while output was below

potential. At other times, output was above potential, yet inflation was low. The

SRIA curve is not stable.

There is a simple explanation for this instability: the level of cyclical unemployment

is not the only factor that affects wages. For one thing, expectations of inflation

also matter. Take the case of a union contract. If workers and firms expect that inflation

will be 3 percent per year over the life of the contract, then the nominal wage called

for in the contract will rise 3 percent per year even if the negotiated real wage remains

constant. Employers are willing to let the nominal wage increase, because they

believe they will be able to sell what they produce at higher prices.

If unemployment is low and people are expecting inflation, wages may rise even

faster than is necessary simply to offset expected inflation. When unemployment

is low and output above potential, workers enjoy better job prospects and are more

likely to quit to take better jobs, while firms will find it harder to hire replacements.

Wages will rise faster as firms try both to prevent their existing workers from leaving

and to attract new workers. If an inflation rate of 3 percent is expected, nominal

wages might rise at 5 percent per year (3 percent to compensate for increases in

the cost of living and 2 percent because labor markets are tight). If workers and

firms expect a much higher rate of inflation, say, 10 percent, then low unemployment

may lead money wages to rise at 12 percent per year (10 percent to compensate for

the rising cost of living, plus 2 percent because labor markets are tight).

Because expectations of inflation affect actual inflation, the SRIA curve shows the

relationship between output (relative to potential) and inflation, for a given expected

rate of inflation. This is represented diagrammatically in Figure 37.6. A vertical line

is drawn at the level of full-employment output Y f to indicate that Y f does not depend

824 ∂ CHAPTER 37 INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!