02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

model of consumer choice that was developed in this chapter. Instead, they argue that

a theory of consumer choice should be based on how people actually make decisions.

Behavioral economists therefore draw on the findings of psychologists who conduct

laboratory experiments to study that question. As a sign of the growing importance

of this work, the 2002 Nobel Prize in Economics was shared by a psychologist, Daniel

Kahneman, whose research has heavily influenced the new field.

Behavioral economics takes as its starting point a number of findings that appear

to be inconsistent with the basic model of consumer choice we have developed in

this chapter. A few of them, discussed below, illustrate the types of evidence on which

behavioral economists focus.

Endowment Effects A large body of evidence suggests that the simple act of

possessing something can alter a person’s preferences. Consider the following experiment

involving a group of college undergraduates, half of whom were given college

coffee mugs that sold for $6.00 at the college bookstore. The students were then

allowed to participate in a market in which mugs could be bought and sold. One

might expect that those students with mugs who valued them least would end up

selling them to those without mugs who valued them most. Since the coffee mugs had

been distributed randomly, about half should trade hands. In fact, very few trades

took place. The experimenters found that the median price demanded by mug sellers

was $5.25, and the median amount buyers were willing to spend was around

$2.25. Initially, there were no reasons to expect predictable differences in how

students valued coffee mugs; but the mere fact of being given a mug seemed to make

individuals value mugs more highly.

This phenomenon is called the endowment effect. In the standard model of consumer

choice, individuals purchase those goods that they value more than the dollars

they have to give up to make the purchase. But people are not expected to value

more highly those items that they happen to possess. In another experiment, college

students were given either a lottery ticket or $2.00. They were then allowed to

exchange whichever they had received for the other; that is, a student who had been

given a lottery ticket could turn it in and get $2.00, or a student who had received $2.00

could exchange it for a lottery ticket. Surprisingly, at least from the perspective of

the standard model of consumer choice, very few students wanted to make the trade.

Those who received lottery tickets seemed to prefer them to the cash; those who

received the cash preferred it to the ticket. Since the two groups of students were

otherwise similar, there was no reason to expect that those who happened to receive

lottery tickets would value them more than did the students given cash.

Loss Aversion The standard model of consumer choice assumes that individuals’

well-defined preferences for goods do not depend on whether they actually have

those items. The endowment effect may reflect what psychologists have called loss

aversion. Individuals seem to be particularly sensitive to losses. Once the students

had mugs in their possession, they didn’t want to give them up; thus they set the

sale price above what they would have been willing to pay for a mug in the first place.

Similarly, a person with $1,100 who then loses $100 feels worse than someone with

$900 who then finds $100. Even though both ultimately have the same amount of

money, their feelings about their situations are very different.

120 ∂ CHAPTER 5 THE CONSUMPTION DECISION

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!