02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

TAXES AND EFFICIENCY

Economists use the law of demand and supply to study the impact of taxes on

consumers and producers. In Chapter 4 we learned that taxes imposed on producers

can be passed on, or shifted, to consumers in the form of higher prices. There,

two examples were contrasted. In the first, the law of supply and demand was used

to study the impact of a tax on cigarette producers. When the demand for the taxed

good is very inelastic, as is true of cigarettes, most of the burden of the tax is shifted

to consumers. The second example involved a tax on one particular type of cheese,

cheddar. In this case, the demand for the taxed good is very elastic, since close substitutes

for cheddar cheese are available. When demand is elastic, most of the tax is

borne by producers. Using the concepts of consumer surplus, producer surplus, and

efficiency, we can gain additional insights into the effects of a tax.

Figure 10.3 shows the markets for cigarettes in panel A and the market for cheddar

cheese in panel B. In each case, the equilibrium quantity without a tax is denoted

by Q 0 . The tax on the output of an industry paid by firms can be thought of as increasing

the costs of production. This increase in cost shifts the supply curve up by the

amount of the tax. Because the demand curve for cigarettes is relatively inelastic, the

main impact of the tax is to raise the price to consumers. The price received by producers

falls slightly, as does the quantity produced in the new equilibrium. In contrast,

when the demand curve is relatively elastic, as shown in panel B for cheddar

cheese, the effect is to cause a larger fall in the price producers receive and a smaller

rise in the price paid by consumers.

The figure also shows what happens to consumer surplus when a good is taxed.

In panel A, the entire blue area is equal to consumer surplus without the tax. After

the tax, consumer surplus is equal only to the blue hatched area. Producer surplus

is also reduced. It is equal to the entire orange region without the tax and the orange

hatched area with the tax. Because the demand curve for cigarettes is inelastic, the

reduction in consumer surplus is greater than the reduction in producer surplus,

reflecting the fact that here the burden of the tax is shifted mainly to consumers.

While both consumer surplus and producer surplus fall, not all of this is lost to

society—after all, the government collects revenue from the tax on cigarettes, and

this revenue is then available to spend on government services. The tax revenue

that is collected equals the tax per unit of output times the quantity of output produced.

The difference between the price consumers pay and the price received by

producers is equal to the tax on each unit of output. So the tax revenues collected

will equal the area outlined in green. When we add up consumer surplus, producer

surplus, and the revenue collected by the government, we can see that this total is

less than the total surplus without the tax—the efficiency cost of the tax is measured

by the area outlined in orange. This is called the deadweight loss caused by a

tax. A tax thus has a cost beyond the revenue actually collected by the government.

Panel B illustrates the situation for a market in which the demand curve is relatively

elastic. Here, the deadweight loss of the tax (the area outlined in orange) is

larger. Because consumers are more sensitive to price when the demand curve is

elastic, the tax causes them to substitute away from the taxed good. The tax “distorts”

consumers’ choices more in this case, and the resulting efficiency loss is larger.

220 ∂ CHAPTER 10 THE EFFICIENCY OF COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!