02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Thinking Like an Economist

TRADE-OFFS AND CHOICES

When economists analyze the decisions of individual households

making consumption purchases, they focus on two

aspects. First, what are the choices available to a given household?

These are defined by the household’s income and the

prices of the different goods it could purchase. With limited

income, buying more of one thing means buying less of something

else—the household faces trade-offs. Second, what are

the preferences of the household? Faced with the same possibilities,

different individuals will make different choices

because they vary in what they like to do or consume.

Economists use this same perspective to analyze actions

by economic policymakers. First, they focus on the trade-offs.

In the case of cyclical unemployment and inflation, they ask

what the short-run trade-offs are—if unemployment is reduced

slightly, how much will inflation rise over, say, the next year?

And they need to understand the long-run trade-offs. Will the

reduction in unemployment be only temporary? Once the policymakers

understand the trade-offs, they can assess the costs

and benefits of the different options and decide on the actual

policies they want to implement. A policymaker who believes

inflation is very costly will make different choices than one

who sees its costs as less significant. Even if they agree about

the way the economy behaves, differences in preferences will

lead to differences in policy recommendations.

in markets, but they have little confidence in the ability of governments to improve

macroeconomic performance. Indeed, some believe that intervention is

counterproductive, for two reasons.

First, they recognize that there are important lags that make policymaking difficult.

It takes time for the government to recognize a problem—and the lags in getting

data, revisions in preliminary data, and the often conflicting information available

can leave policymakers in great uncertainty as they try to assess the state of the

economy. And after a problem is recognized, more time is needed before action can

be taken. The Federal Open Meeting Committee of the Federal Reserve meets frequently,

but fiscal policy actions may require congressional approval, which can

easily take many months to secure. Finally, there are time lags between when a policy

action is taken and when it has an impact on the economy. Interest rate changes by

the Fed, for example, take six months or more to significantly affect output and even

longer to influence inflation. Lags by themselves would not be a problem if the government

could accurately forecast. But everyone, including government economists,

sees the future with a cloudy crystal ball.

Because of these lags, the action may no longer be appropriate by the time its

effects are fully realized. Expansionary policies may finally take effect just as the

economy is already recovering, thereby encouraging inflation. Or contractionary

policies designed to slow inflation might affect the economy just as it is starting to

enter a recession, worsening the subsequent rise in unemployment.

Second, critics of strong interventionist policies argue that there are systematic

political reasons why interventionists are often misguided. Politicians want the

economy to expand before an election. They might boost government spending to overheat

the economy, winning gains in employment before the election but incurring

costs, in terms of higher inflation, that show up only after the election. In recent

THE GOALS OF MACROECONOMIC POLICY ∂ 845

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!