02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

the oil embargo imposed by the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries

(OPEC) as a result of the 1973 Arab-Israeli War. The sharp increases in inflation

caused by these oil price increases are clearly visible in Figure 37.1. As this experience

suggests, other factors besides cyclical unemployment and expectations

influence inflation.

The basic relationship between output and inflation that we summarized in

the inflation adjustment curve started with the Phillips curve relationship between

cyclical unemployment and wage increases. We then argued that wages and

prices move in tandem, and thus the SRIA curve links cyclical unemployment

and inflation. While Figure 37.3 shows that wages and prices generally move

together, it also shows that inflation exceeded wage increases at the time of the

oil price shocks. The oil price changes altered the relationship between wages

and prices.

The reason is straightforward. Wages are a large part of the costs that firms face.

But firms have other important costs as well, and the cost of the energy involved

in producing is one of them. For a given increase in wages, prices will rise more

as these other costs rise. The oil price hikes of the 1970s increased inflation

relative to wages, as shown in Figure 37.3. Such events are called inflation

shocks, and they produce temporary shifts in the SRIA curve. For given inflation

expectations and output, a positive inflation shock increases the actual rate

of inflation.

Some economists have argued that the late 1990s were a repeat of the 1970s but

in reverse. That is, the United States was again hit by an inflation shock—but this

time, a negative shock that temporarily shifted the SRIA curve down. Inflation was

lower at each level of output. Put another way, we can say that inflation was lower

at each level of cyclical unemployment. Two pieces of evidence are consistent with

this interpretation. First, if we again look back to Figure 37.3, we see that just as

inflation was pushed above the rate of wage increases by the positive inflation shocks

of the 1970s, so during the 1990s inflation fell below wage increases. Second, at the

end of the 1990s, unemployment plummeted. In April 2000, for example, the overall

jobless rate fell to 3.9 percent, the lowest level since 1970. Despite this evidence

of tight labor markets, inflation had not increased, as the SRIA curve would imply

should happen. This stability, too, might indicate that the economy was experiencing

a negative inflation shock.

Fundamentals of Inflation

CYCLICAL UNEMPLOYMENT

Movements in cyclical unemployment cause fluctuations in the rate of wage growth

relative to productivity growth. In tight labor markets, wages will rise more rapidly;

in periods of high unemployment, wage growth will slow and wages may decline.

These fluctuations in firms’ wage costs are passed through into prices and lead to

fluctuations in the rate of inflation. As a consequence, fluctuations in the output gap

will be positively associated with fluctuations in the rate of inflation.

SHORT-RUN INFLATION ADJUSTMENT ∂ 831

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!