02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

PRICE (p )

p m

p c

Marginal

revenue

curve

Q m Q c

FIGURE 13.1

QUANTITY (Q )

Marginal

cost

curve

Demand

curve

WHY MONOPOLY OUTPUT IS INEFFICIENT

With perfect competition, price is set equal to marginal

cost: output is at quantity Q c , and price at p c . A monopolist

will set marginal revenue equal to marginal cost,

and will produce at quantity Q m and price p m , where the

market price exceeds marginal cost.

A monopolist who sets marginal revenue equal to marginal cost

produces at a lower level of output than a corresponding competitive

industry—an industry with the same demand curve and costs but in

which there are many producers rather than one—where price equals

marginal cost. Figure 13.1 shows that the monopoly output, Q m , is

smaller than the competitive output, Q c , where the price under

competition, p c , equals marginal cost. The price under monopoly, p m ,

is higher than p c .

The price of a good, by definition, measures how much an individual

is willing to pay for an extra unit of it. It measures, in other words,

the marginal benefit of the good to the purchaser. With perfect competition,

price equals marginal cost, so that in equilibrium the marginal

benefit of an extra unit of a good to the individual (the price) is just

equal to the marginal cost to the firm of producing it. At the monopolist’s

lower level of output, the marginal benefit of producing an extra

unit—the price individuals are willing to pay for an extra unit—exceeds

marginal cost.

By comparing the monopolist’s production decision with the collective

decisions regarding output made by firms in a competitive

market, we can estimate the value of the loss to society incurred by a

monopoly. To simplify the analysis, in Figure 13.2 marginal cost is

assumed to be constant, the horizontal line at the competitive price

p c . The monopolist produces an output of Q m , at the point where marginal

revenue equals marginal cost, and finds that it can charge p m ,

the price on the demand curve corresponding to the output Q m .

Two kinds of loss result, both related to the concept of consumer surplus introduced

in Chapter 5. There we saw that the downward-sloping demand curve implies

a bounty to most consumers. At points to the left of the intersection of the price line

and demand curve, people are willing to pay more for the good than they have to.

With competition, the consumer surplus in Figure 13.2 is the entire shaded area

between the demand curve and the line at p c .

The monopolist cuts into this surplus. First, it charges a higher price, p m , than

would be obtained in the competitive situation. This loss is measured by the rectangle

ABCD, the extra price multiplied by the quantity actually produced and consumed.

It is not a loss to society as a whole but a transfer of income, as the higher

price winds up as revenues for the monopoly. But the monopolist also reduces the

quantity produced. While production in a competitive market would be Q c , a monopoly

produces the lower amount, Q m . This second kind of loss is a complete loss

to society, and is called the deadweight loss of a monopoly. Consumers lose the

surplus to the right of Q m , denoted by triangle ABG, with no resulting gain to

the monopolist.

Some economists, such as Arnold Harberger of UCLA, have argued that these

costs of monopoly are relatively small, amounting to perhaps 3 percent of the monopolist’s

output value. Others believe the losses from restricting output are higher.

Whichever argument is right, output restriction is only one source of the inefficiencies

monopolies introduce into the economy.

290 ∂ CHAPTER 13 GOVERNMENT POLICIES TOWARD COMPETITION

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!