02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

lion. If any of the components of E changes by $1, equilibrium output changes by

1/(1 − (1 − t)MPC). For example, suppose E increases to $4 trillion. Equilibrium output

rises to $15 trillion. The multiplier is equal to the change in output ($15 trillion −

$12.5 trillion = $2.5 trillion) per dollar change in E ($1 trillion), or 2.5. This can also

be found directly as 1/(1 − (1 − t)MPC) = 1/[1 − (1 − .25) × .8] = 2.5. By contrast, the multiplier

without taxes would be 1/(1 − MPC) = 5, or twice as large. The reason that

the multiplier is larger without taxes is simple. Without taxes, every dollar of extra

income translates into 80 cents of extra spending. With taxes, when income goes

up by a dollar, disposable income rises by 75 cents and consumption increases by

only .8 × .75 cents = 60 cents.

EXPECTATIONS OF FUTURE INCOME

Current disposable income is a key determinant of consumption, but households’ decisions

about how much to consume are also influenced by their expectations about

future income. If households expect that their income will fall in the future, they are likely

to reduce their current consumption so that they can save more. By saving more today,

they will be better able to preserve their standard of living when their income declines

later. Thus, a projected or expected tax increase that will reduce future disposable

income may reduce consumption spending even before it goes into effect. Conversely,

if households expect that their future income will rise, they are likely to increase their

consumption spending immediately. A projected or expected tax decrease can lead

to a rise in consumption before households actually see their disposable income go up.

The dependence of current spending on expectations about future income has

another very important implication. Households are likely to increase spending

more when their current income rises if they expect the income increase to be permanent—that

is, if they expect both their current and future income to be higher.

Similarly, a tax cut viewed as temporary is likely to lead to a smaller increase in consumption

than a tax cut that is viewed as permanent. Another way to express this

implication is to say that the marginal propensity to consume out of permanent

changes in income will be larger than the marginal propensity to consume out of

temporary or transitory changes in income.

If consumption changes when expected future income changes, even when current

income is still the same, then shifts in expectations will cause the aggregate

expenditure schedule to shift. When households become more optimistic about their

future income, aggregate consumption will increase at each level of current disposable

income. The result is an increase in aggregate expenditures at each level of

national income, shifting the aggregate expenditure schedule upward.

WEALTH

A third factor that is important for determining consumption is household wealth.

Wealthier households will consume more (at each level of current income). Just as

changes in individuals’ wealth will affect their consumption choices, so changes in

aggregate wealth will affect aggregate consumption.

CONSUMPTION ∂ 671

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!