02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

the socially optimal level of production. The tax, t, increases the firm’s costs of producing

steel, shifting up the market supply curve. The new market equilibrium is

now at the socially optimal quantity Q s . The equilibrium price is p s ; purchasers of

steel pay a price that correctly reflects the social cost of producing steel. Doing so

ensures that the marginal benefits are set equal to the marginal costs. Steelproducing

firms receive the market price less the tax, p s – t, an amount that equals

their private marginal cost of producing steel.

Taxes on pollution are similar to fines for violating regulations in one respect—

both increase the cost of and thereby discourage pollution. But taxes differ from regulation

in a fundamental way. Regulations are a clumsy tool. They penalize firms for

polluting over a specific level, but polluters who stay just below that level get off scotfree.

Pollution taxes can be set so that they reduce aggregate pollution by the same

amount as a regulator would under a command and control system. But the economic

effects are very different. Taxes add the cost of pollution to the costs that a

company has to cover to remain in business. As a result, companies have an incentive

to reduce their pollution as far as possible and to find new, low-cost ways of reducing

pollution or to devise new production methods that are less polluting, rather than

keeping pollution just below the legal standard. This is “efficient pollution abatement,”

as the producers who pollute less gain their reward in lower costs.

Subsidies such as tax credits for pollution-abatement devices are an alternative

way of providing incentives to reduce pollution. Subsidies are economically inefficient.

Take the case of steel firms. When they receive subsidies, firms are not paying the

full costs. Part of the costs are being picked up by the government. Producers therefore

can sell (and users can buy) steel for less than its full cost of production, and

steel and pollution production thus remain above the socially efficient level. Clearly,

firms prefer subsidies to taxes.

THE MARKETABLE PERMIT RESPONSE

Still another approach to curbing pollution is marketable permits. Companies

purchase (or are granted) a permit from the government that allows them to

emit a certain amount of pollution. Again, the government can set the amount so

that the company produces the same level of pollution as it would under the command

and control approach. However, companies are allowed to sell their permits.

Thus, if a company cuts its pollution in half, it can sell some of its allowance

to another company that wants to expand production (and hence its emission

of pollutants).

The incentive effects of marketable permits are very much like those of taxes. A

market for pollution permits encourages development of the best possible antipollution

devices, rather than keeping the pollution just under some governmentset

limit. If the government wishes to reduce pollution over time, the permits can

be designed to reduce the amount of pollution they allow by a prescribed amount

each year. In the United States, this sort of shrinking marketable permit was

used to reduce the amount of lead in gasoline during the early 1980s. Variants of

this idea have recently been adopted to help control other forms of air pollution,

such as sulfur dioxide.

POLICY RESPONSES TO PROBLEMS IN THE ENVIRONMENT ∂ 413

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!