02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

demand for them would increase. And restraining the operating

system company from writing applications would at least

prevent a repeat of what had happened with Netscape and the

browser market.

Some critics thought the judge, in approving the Justice

Department’s recommendations in 2000, went too far; others

thought he did not go far enough. Those in the former camp

worried that he overlooked important economies of scope—

efficiencies that arose from the close interaction between those

writing the operating system and those developing applications.

These advantages, they contended, more than offset the

disadvantages from the loss in competition. Moreover, they

believed that Microsoft’s monopoly power was temporary;

within a few years, surely competition would erode its dominant

position. Already, Linux was rapidly growing as an

alternative operating system. They argued that Microsoft

had achieved its dominant position by strong innovation,

and it was wrong to punish this success now by breaking the

company up.

But critics on the other side said that at least a significant

part of Microsoft’s success was due to its ruthless business

practices, and such behavior should not go unpunished. And

more was at stake: Microsoft represented a threat to innovation.

Few would invest in innovation if they believed that any

innovation threatening Microsoft’s competitive position would

be suppressed by Microsoft. Many Silicon Valley firms shared

this fear.

These critics worried that the Microsoft application company

still might not write programs for other operating systems,

that there might be sweetheart deals between the two

companies; they argued for other approaches to changes

Microsoft’s incentives. For instance, some suggested limiting

intellectual property protection—and requiring the disclosure

of the code—for operating systems of a firm with a

dominant position (like Microsoft) to, say, three to five years.

Doing so would automatically create a competitor to, say,

Windows XP—the freely available Windows 2000. Only if

Windows XP were markedly better than Windows 2000

would people pay anything for it. This approach would enhance

Microsoft’s incentives to innovate. Meanwhile, application

programmers would have an incentive to write programs

that worked better and better with the freely available 2000

operating system. The hope was that out of this competition,

consumers would benefit not only from lower prices but

also from innovations, possibly leading to programs that

crash less often and are tailored better to the needs of particular

groups of users, that run faster, and that perform

new tasks.

ous when goods produced by different firms are imperfect substitutes. What, for

example, is the market for beer? Those in the industry might claim that premium

beers and discount beers really constitute two different markets, as relatively few

customers cross over from one to the other. In the 1950s, DuPont had a virtual monopoly

on the market for clear wrapping paper, but it fought off charges of monopoly by

arguing that its product was one among several “wrapping materials.” It claimed

that brown paper was a good, though not perfect, substitute for clear wrapping paper,

and that DuPont did not have a particularly large share of this larger market.

Legal Criteria Today, the courts look at two criteria in defining a market and

market power. First, they consider the extent to which a change in price for one

product affects the demand for another. If an increase in the price of aluminum has

a large positive effect on the demand for steel, then steel and aluminum may be considered

to be in the same market—the market for metals. Second, if a firm can raise

its price, say by 5 percent, and lose only a relatively small fraction of its sales, then

it is “large”—that is, it has market power.

ANTITRUST POLICIES ∂ 303

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!