02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

curve. A. W. Phillips was a New Zealander who taught economics in

England during the 1950s. He examined data from England on unemployment

and the rate of increases in nominal or money wages. He found

a negative relationship between the two, and this relationship is known

as the Phillips curve. At higher unemployment rates, money wages rose

more slowly. At lower unemployment rates, money wages rose more

quickly. The relationship he found is shown in Figure 37.2.

The logic behind the Phillips curve is straightforward. If unemployment

is low, firms have greater difficulty hiring workers. The result is

upward pressure on wages, as firms attempt to attract workers by paying

more. If unions and firms negotiate over wages, the union will be in a

stronger bargaining position, better able to get larger wage increases, if

labor markets are “tight.” At low unemployment rates, workers are more

likely to decide that the time is right to look for another job. Firms that

do not keep pace with wage increases elsewhere may discover that their

best workers are leaving. If workers believe that finding another job will

be easy, they may worry less about being fired. As a consequence, they may

not work as hard. To maintain worker productivity, firms will need to

raise wages more rapidly. In contrast, if unemployment is high, there will

be little upward pressure on real wages. Money wages will increase more

slowly or even decrease for some workers.

PERCENT CHANGE IN MONEY WAGES

10

8

6

4

2

0

Figure 37.2

Phillips

curve

1 2 3 4 5 6

UNEMPLOYMENT RATE (%)

THE ORIGINAL PHILLIPS CURVE

The Phillips curve shows that the rate of wage growth

rises as the unemployment rate falls. The curve shown

here is the one Phillips plotted in 1958 for the British

economy.

From Wages to Prices The Phillips curve relates unemployment to the rate at

which wages are changing. The bigger the imbalance between labor demand and

labor supply, the faster money wages will change.

The link between the rate at which wages are changing and the rate at which

prices are changing—the rate of inflation—is direct. Labor costs are, for most businesses,

the major component of their costs of production. In competitive markets,

prices will move in tandem with marginal costs, and an increase in wages will translate

directly into an increase in the marginal costs of production. Some firms, at

least in the short run, use a simple rule of thumb in setting prices—they set price

as a given markup over costs (e.g., 120 percent of costs). Under that system, changes

in the rate at which wages are changing will translate directly into changes in

the rate of inflation. Figure 37.3 shows the close historical relationship between

the two.

Because they move together, we can replace the rate of nominal wage increase

on the vertical axis of the Phillips curve with the rate of inflation. Even though Phillips

himself originally studied the behavior of unemployment and wages, it is more

common today to see Phillips curves that have the inflation rate on the vertical axis.

We will adopt this practice from now on when we use the Phillips curve.

The Phillips Curve and Cyclical Unemployment The relation between

inflation and unemployment that Phillips found for the United Kingdom also has

been found for other countries. Figure 37.4, which shows inflation and unemployment

for the United States during different periods, reveals an important fact. The

Phillips curve seems to shift. During periods of relative low inflation, such as 1960

to 1969 and 1984 to 2003, the inflation-unemployment relation is closer to the origin

SHORT-RUN INFLATION ADJUSTMENT ∂ 821

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!