02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

The Status Quo Bias Loss aversion and endowment effects lead to behavior

that exhibits a bias in favor of the status quo. In the example just given, the status

quo or reference point of the first person is the $1,100 he had, so he feels worse off

when he has only $1,000. The reference level of the second person was $900, so she

feels better off when she has $1,000. In the basic model of consumer choice outlined

in this chapter, we assumed that individuals’ utility depended on the absolute level

of their consumption. If reference points are important, utility may instead depend

on the difference between an individual’s current consumption and a reference level

of consumption. This reference level might be recent levels of consumption—a certain

standard of living to which people become accustomed. Or it might be the consumption

levels of an individual’s peer group, an idea captured in the phrase “keeping

up with the Joneses.”

The tendency of individuals to accept whatever happens to be the default among

a number of options illustrates the importance of the status quo. For example, many

employers offer their employees the option of participating in a 401(k) savings plan,

a way to set aside before-tax income for retirement. If the default is automatic participation,

so that employees must actively decide to opt out of the plan, then most

employees end up contributing. If the default is to not participate, requiring employees

to sign up for the plan, the fraction of employees who participate is much lower.

Ignoring status quo effects may undercut major public policy initiatives. In 2003,

the U.S. federal government introduced a medical drug benefit as part of Medicare,

the health insurance program for older Americans. To obtain discounts on prescription

drugs, seniors had to sign up for a “drug discount card.” The default option was

to not sign up. According to a survey conducted by the Harvard School of Public

Health and the Kaiser Family Foundation, only about 10 percent of eligible seniors

had signed up by the middle of 2004. The status quo effect may have been one factor

at work.

Implications These examples, and many others that behavioral economists

have investigated, suggest the economist’s simple model of choice is incomplete. But

what is critical for an analysis of market economies is understanding how the behavior

uncovered by psychologists and behavioral economists affects market demand

curves. Do we need to change the basic ideas developed in this chapter about how

consumers respond to changes in prices? Broadly speaking, the answer is clearly

no. Individuals do respond to incentives—as the price of a good falls, we expect more

consumers will purchase it. As price rises, less is demanded. The findings from

behavioral economics do suggest, however, that preferences can depend on what

individuals view as the status quo, and that consumers may display a greater reluctance

to change than the basic economic model would predict. This reluctance to

change, reflected in the endowment effect and the status quo effect, may reduce

their sensitivity to incentives. These effects may help explain why economists often

observe individuals passing up the opportunity to make exchanges that appear to be

advantageous.

Behavioral economists have developed new insights into saving behavior, as well.

We will consider some of them in Chapter 9, where we will discuss the factors that

affect household decisions about how much to save.

LOOKING BEYOND THE BASIC MODEL ∂ 121

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!