02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Joan chooses among the points on this budget constraint according to her personal

preferences. Consider, for example, point D, where Joan is consuming very

little during her working life. Since she is spending very little in the present, any

additional consumption now will have a high marginal value. She will be relatively

eager to substitute present consumption for future consumption. At the other

extreme, if she is consuming a great deal in the present, say at point F, additional

consumption today will have a relatively low marginal value, while future consumption

will have a high marginal value. Hence, she will be relatively eager to save more

for the future. She chooses a point in between, E, where consumption in the two

periods is not too different. She has smoothed her consumption. That is, consumption

in each of the two different periods is about the same. This kind of saving,

intended to smooth consumption over a worker’s lifetime and to provide for retirement,

is called life-cycle saving. In Figure 9.1, the difference between the first-period

income, w, and what she consumes in the first period is her saving.

The Time Value of Money Because you can earn interest on your savings,

the cost of a dollar of current consumption is more than simply $1.00 of future consumption.

As we learned in Chapter 2, calculating costs correctly is one of the basic

steps in making rational decisions. But what if we are comparing costs that occur at

different times, such as the cost of current versus future consumption? Or to take

a more specific example, suppose one store advertises a car stereo system for $400

and another advertises it for $425 with no payment for a full year. How can we compare

these two? If you have the $400 to spend today, is it cheaper to pay $400 right

now for the stereo or to pay $425 in one year?

To think about this comparison, consider what you could do with your $400 if you

opted to buy from the store that lets you delay your payment. You might put the

money in a bank. When you deposit money in a bank, you have lent it your money.

In return, the bank pays you interest. If the interest rate is 5 percent per year, you

will receive $420 in a year—the $20 is the interest payment, while the $400 is the

repayment of the principal, the original amount you lent to the bank.

The interest rate is a price, and like other prices, it describes a trade-off. If the

interest rate is 5 percent, by giving up $1.00 worth of consumption today, a saver

can have $1.05 worth of consumption next year. Thus, the rate of interest tells us how

much future consumption we can get by giving up $1.00 worth of current consumption.

It tells us the relative price of purchases in the present and in the future.

Because interest rates are normally positive, $1.00 today becomes more than a

dollar in the future. Thus a dollar today is worth more than a dollar in the future.

Economists call this phenomenon the time value of money. The concept of present

discounted value tells us precisely how to measure the time value of money.

The present discounted value of $100 a year from now is what you would pay today

for $100 in a year. Suppose the interest rate is 5 percent. If you put $95.24 in the

bank today, then at the end of a year you will receive $4.76 in interest, which together

with the original principal will total $100. Thus, $95.24 is the present discounted

value of $100 one year from now, if the interest rate is 5 percent.

There is a simple formula for calculating the present discounted value of any

amount to be received a year from now: just divide the amount by 1 plus the annual

rate of interest (often denoted by r).

SUPPLY IN THE CAPITAL MARKET ∂ 193

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!