02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

in the ADI curve pushed the economy into a recession, with output at E 1 , below the

economy’s full-employment output at point E 0 . If the aggregate demand curve

remains at ADI 1 , inflation will eventually fall and the economy will reach full employment

at point E 2 with an inflation rate of π 2 . If inflation adjusts slowly, it may take

a long time for full employment to be restored. An expansionary fiscal or monetary

policy that shifts the aggregate demand curve to the right would push the short-run

equilibrium output level closer to full employment. If the ADI curve is shifted all the

way to ADI 0 , full employment is restored at the original rate of inflation, π 0 .

Shifts in the Inflation

Adjustment Curve

So far, we have concentrated on the impact of shifts in the ADI curve on the economy.

Such a focus is natural in that aggregate expenditures determine output (and

employment) in the short run, and inflation typically adjusts relatively slowly. But

economies also experience disturbances that directly affect inflation. Two of the

most important are changes in energy prices and shifts in potential GDP.

INFLATION (π)

E 1

π 0

Y f E 0

IA 0

π 1 IA 1

ADI 0

Figure 31.9

Y 1

OUTPUT (Y )

THE IMPACT OF AN INFLATION SHOCK

An increase in the cost of production at each level of

output increases the inflation rate, shifting the inflation

adjustment curve up, from IA 0 to IA 1 . The short-run equilibrium

is at the point of intersection between the inflation

adjustment and ADI curves. The upward shift in the

inflation adjustment curve moves the economy to E 1 ,

where output has fallen to Y 1 . If there are no further inflation

shocks, inflation declines because output is below its

full-employment level. Eventually, full employment and

an inflation rate of π 0 are restored.

CHANGES IN ENERGY PRICES

For a given level of cyclical unemployment, inflation can be affected by

shocks that alter firms’ costs of production. For example, during the

1970s, oil prices increased dramatically. Oil prices also rose substantially

in 2004, because of both greater demand for oil as the economies

of China and the United States grew and fears of disruptions in supply

as the fighting in Iraq continued. By raising the price of energy, an

increase in oil prices pushes up the costs of production. In response,

firms will raise prices, leading in turn to a jump in the inflation rate.

We can analyze the consequences of an inflation shock such as an

oil price increase using the ADI curve and inflation adjustment line. To

do so, suppose the economy is initially at full employment with an inflation

rate equal to π 0 . This condition is shown as point E 0 in Figure 31.9.

The inflation shock causes inflation to increase to π 1 , as shown by the

upward shift in the inflation adjustment curve to IA 1 . The new equilibrium

is at E 1 . Economic disturbances that shift the inflation adjustment

curve—inflation shocks—are often also called supply shocks.

The economy will not remain at point E 1 , however. Over time, inflation

will decline because the economy is operating below potential GDP.

As inflation falls, the IA curve shifts back down. Eventually, the equilibrium

returns to point E 0 , with the inflation rate and output back at their

initial values.

Supply shocks present policymakers with difficult choices. To prevent

output from declining and unemployment from rising, the central

704 ∂ CHAPTER 31 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND INFLATION

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!