02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

let us first review why competition may not be viable when average costs are

declining over the relevant range of output.

If two firms divide the market between them, each faces higher average costs

than if either one controlled the whole market. By undercutting its rival, a firm would

be able to capture the entire market and reduce its average costs. By the same token,

a natural monopolist knows that it can charge a price above its average cost without

worrying about entry. Rivals that might enter the market, trying to capture

some of the profits, know that the natural monopolist has lower costs because of its

larger scale of production, and so can always undercut them.

Even under these conditions, some economists have argued that a monopolist

would not in fact charge higher than average costs, because a rival could enter any

time and grab the whole market. Analysts have argued that in the software industry,

such a worry leads Microsoft to lower its prices. By keeping its prices lower

than it would if no potential rival could enter the market, Microsoft promotes the

wider use of its software. As people use programs such as Microsoft’s Word and

Excel, they become familiar with them and more reluctant to switch to something

new, thereby creating a greater obstacle for a new entrant to overcome. Similarly,

in small countries such as New Zealand, the threat that a large foreign firm could enter

the market and take it over if the local monopoly charged above average costs

restrains the monopoly’s ability to raise its prices. On this argument, all that is

required to keep prices low is potential competition.

Most economists are not so optimistic about the effectiveness of potential, as

opposed to actual, competition. They note that potential competition has not been

able to keep airline prices down in those markets in which actual competition is

limited to one or two carriers.

In the late 1970s and 1980s, many governments became convinced that competition,

however imperfect, might be better than regulation, and they began a process

of deregulation. Deregulation focused on industries such as airlines, railroads,

and trucking in which increasing returns to scale are limited. Recall that it is

increasing returns to scale that lead to declining average costs. Thus, reformers

believed that competition had a chance of succeeding in these industries. Government

also sought to distinguish parts of an industry where competition might

work from parts where competition was unlikely to be effective. In the telephone

industry, for example, competition among several carriers was strong for longdistance

telephone service, and there were few economies of scale in the production

of telephone equipment. Accordingly, regulation in these areas was reduced

or eliminated.

The virtues of competition have been realized, for the most part. Trucking—

where the arguments for government regulation seemed most suspect—was

perhaps the most unambiguous success story, as prices have fallen significantly.

Railroads appear more financially sound than they did under regulation. But coal

producers, who rely on railroads to ship their coal, complain that railroads have

used their monopoly power to charge them much higher tariffs.

Airline deregulation has become more controversial. After its initial success—

marked by new firms, lower fares, and more extensive routings—a rash of

bankruptcies has reduced the number of airlines. Many airports, including those

at St. Louis, Atlanta, and Denver, are dominated by one or two carriers, and

POLICIES TOWARD NATURAL MONOPOLIES ∂ 297

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!