02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

matters? Some economists, led by the Nobel laureate Ronald Coase of the University

of Chicago Law School, argue that government should simply rearrange property

rights. Coase’s theorem says that with appropriately designed property rights,

markets could take care of externalities without direct government intervention.

Consider, for example, the case of a small lake in which anyone can fish without

charge. Each fisherman ignores the fact that the more fish he takes out of the lake,

the fewer there are for others to take out. No fisherman has an incentive to worry

about whether there will be fish in the lake in the future, either. Why should he?

After all, if he leaves fish in the lake today, someone else might take them out tomorrow.

If all fishermen think this way, the lake will quickly be overfished, likely to the

point of wiping out the fish stock. If the government were to rearrange property

rights and grant the right to fish to a single individual, then she would have every

incentive to fish efficiently. There would no longer be any externality. She would

have an incentive to take into account both the long-term and the short-term effects

of her decisions. She would realize that if she fished too much today, the lake would

contain fewer fish tomorrow. If it were a large lake, she might let others do the fishing

and charge them for each fish caught or regulate the amount of fish they could

catch. But the prices she charged and the regulations she imposed would be designed

to ensure that the lake was not overfished.

The point of this example is that the problem of overfishing is solved with

only limited government intervention. All the government has to do is assign the

property rights correctly.

Coase envisioned that once property rights were assigned, market solutions or

bargaining among potential users would ensure efficient outcomes. Consider the

conflict between smokers and nonsmokers over whether to allow smoking in a room.

Smokers confer a negative externality on nonsmokers. Coase suggests a simple solution.

Give the rights to the air to one individual, say, a smoker. He has the right to

decide whether to allow smoking or not. For the sake of simplicity, assume that there

are only two individuals in the room, one a smoker and the other a nonsmoker. If

the value of fresh air to the nonsmoker exceeds the value of smoking to the smoker,

the nonsmoker would offer the smoker enough money to compensate him not to

smoke. Conversely, if the property rights were given to the nonsmoker, and if the

value of smoking to the smoker exceeded the value of fresh air to the nonsmoker,

then the smoker could compensate the nonsmoker.

Coase argued not only that assigning property rights ensures an efficient outcome

but also that how the property rights are assigned affects only the distribution of

income, not economic efficiency. Whether smoking would be allowed would depend

merely on whether the value of smoking to smokers exceeded or was less than the

value of fresh air to nonsmokers.

The appeal of Coase’s theorem is that it assigns a minimal role to government.

Government simply makes the property rights clear, and leaves the efficient outcome

to private markets. Opportunities to apply the theorem are limited, however,

because the costs of reaching an agreement may be high, particularly when large

numbers of individuals are involved. Imagine the difficulties of assigning property

rights to the atmosphere, and arranging that all the individuals adversely affected

by air pollution negotiate with all those contributing to it!

POLICY RESPONSES TO PROBLEMS IN THE ENVIRONMENT ∂ 409

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!