02.05.2020 Views

[Joseph_E._Stiglitz,_Carl_E._Walsh]_Economics(Bookos.org) (1)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

in question. If the price of orange juice rises, consumers have an incentive to buy

less orange juice and to buy apple juice, cranberry juice, or any one of a number of

other drinks instead. If a new tax pushes up the price of gasoline, drivers likewise have

an incentive to reduce their consumption of gas; but doing so may be difficult for

those who have to drive to work in cars with conventional engines. Some may be

able to ride the bus, but many will be hard-pressed to find an alternative means of

transportation. And switching to an electric or hybrid vehicle can be costly.

As these examples illustrate, substitutes exist for almost every good or service,

but substitution will be more difficult for some goods and services than for others.

When substitution is difficult, an increase in the price of a good will not cause

the quantity demanded to decrease by much, and a decrease in the price will

not cause the quantity demanded to increase much. In terms of the demand curves

we discussed in Chapter 3, the demand curve for a good with few substitutes

will be relatively steep: changes in price do not cause very large changes in the

quantity demanded.

When substitution is easy, as in the case of orange juice, an increase in price may

lead to a large decrease in the quantity demanded. Ice cream is another example of

a good with many close substitutes. A price increase for ice cream means that frozen

yogurt, gelato, and similar products become relatively less expensive, and the demand

for ice cream would thus significantly decrease. The demand curve for a good with

many substitutes will be relatively flat: changes in price cause large changes in the

quantity demanded.

For many purposes, economists need to be precise about how steep or how flat

the demand curve is. They therefore use the concept of the price elasticity of

demand (for short, the price elasticity or the elasticity of demand), which is defined

as the percentage change in the quantity demanded divided by the percentage change

in price. In mathematical terms,

percentage change in quantity demanded

elasticity of demand = .

percentage change in price

If the quantity demanded changes 8 percent in response to a 2 percent change in

price, then the elasticity of demand is 4.

(Price elasticities of demand are really negative numbers; that is, when the price

increases, quantities demanded are reduced. But the convention is to simply give

the elasticity’s absolute value with the understanding that it is negative.)

It is easiest to calculate the elasticity of demand when there is just a 1 percent

change in price. Then the elasticity of demand is just the percentage change in the

quantity demanded. In the telescoped portion of Figure 4.1A, we see that increasing

the price of orange juice from $2.00 a gallon to $2.02—a 1 percent increase in

price—reduces the demand from 100 million gallons to 98 million, a 2 percent decline.

So the price elasticity of demand for ice cream is 2.

By contrast, assume that the price of gas increases from $2.00 a gallon to $2.02

(again a 1 percent increase in price), as shown in the telescoped portion of Figure

4.1B. This reduces demand from 100 million gallons per year to 99.8 million. Demand

has gone down by 0.2 percent, so the price elasticity of demand is therefore 0.2.

Larger values for price elasticity indicate that demand is more sensitive to changes

in price. Smaller values indicate that demand is less sensitive to price changes.

78 ∂ CHAPTER 4 USING DEMAND AND SUPPLY

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!