04.05.2013 Views

MICHAEL DEMPSEY - Cranfield University

MICHAEL DEMPSEY - Cranfield University

MICHAEL DEMPSEY - Cranfield University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

leadership predominance and, in the perceptions of some managers, a<br />

higher trust environment existed, it could be argued that relations<br />

rested on perceptions of the appropriate relationship between the<br />

parties, thus demonstrating the third dimension of power (Lukes 1974).<br />

There were several instances, over political boundaries, where<br />

technical or physical space issues became political ones and the view<br />

was expressed that only in a financial crisis could, in effect, rationality<br />

defeat power; thus modifying Flyvberg’s (1998) hypothesis that, in open<br />

confrontations, rationality would yield to power. There was also one<br />

clear statement that, in certain circumstances, managers would be<br />

engaged in some Freudian way in trying to find ways to undermine a<br />

‘ridiculous’ membership decision – a situation which Marxist writers<br />

such as Kelly (1988) would probably see as evidence of a<br />

manifestation of the class struggle (though the manager who made the<br />

observation would probably be quick to claim a Marxist pedigree).<br />

This study, then, does not purport to have analysed these<br />

manifestations of power strategies involving trade union managers on<br />

the basis that this would be a one dimensional exercise, given the<br />

nature of the research. It has, though, undertaken an assessment of<br />

the character of managerial boundary management against dimensions<br />

of competition and co-operation. These are dimensions familiar in the<br />

power and conflict resolution literature (see e.g. Deutsch 1973;<br />

Coleman 2003) where they are seen as being at either end of a<br />

continuum of relations. Exhibit 9.12 reveals a pattern of responses<br />

going from one end of the continuum to the other, demonstrating the<br />

impossibility of maintaining, on any practical or theoretical basis, that<br />

trade union managers practise normative stakeholder management in<br />

respect of stakeholders within the union’s democratic structures.<br />

As Chapter 9 points out, the responses in Exhibit 9.12 do not ‘map’<br />

against any notions of greater or lesser degrees of partnership working,<br />

insofar as those are ascertainable. Nor do they relate to the phase of<br />

merger that the union has reached. Exhibit 9.10 sought to estimate<br />

cultural movements on merger so that unions were categorised (no<br />

doubt imprecisely) not only by the extent to which they might engage in<br />

partnership working but how they might have arrived at that position,<br />

using a modification of Fairbrother’s (2000) framework. Before looking<br />

in a little more detail at whether any other ideas of governance can help<br />

to model how union managers and activists relate in that process, there<br />

is one idea about cultural movements that should be flagged up.<br />

Cartwright and Cooper (1996:63) suggest that cultural movement in<br />

mergers is important. As reported in Chapter 2, the key issue for them<br />

in successful mergers is whether the culture of the new organisation<br />

imposes more or less constraints on organisational members as<br />

individuals. Chapter 9 distinguishes between the attitudes of managers<br />

and lay members in situations where culture is moving towards less (or<br />

more) autonomy for managers and/or towards more (or less) autonomy<br />

for activists. It suggests, consistent with Cartwright and Cooper (1996),<br />

397

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!