03.01.2014 Views

sectoral economic costs and benefits of ghg mitigation - IPCC

sectoral economic costs and benefits of ghg mitigation - IPCC

sectoral economic costs and benefits of ghg mitigation - IPCC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Patrick Criqui, Nikos Kouvaritakis <strong>and</strong> Leo Schrattenholzer<br />

heavily affected among clean coal technologies as it was the winner in the reference case<br />

while technologies like wind, solar thermal <strong>and</strong> photovoltaics see big gains in part precisely<br />

because they failed to make significant inroads in the unconstrained case;<br />

- the impact on electricity production by technology follows very closely that <strong>of</strong> installed<br />

capacity. This is particularly true for base load technologies (nuclear <strong>and</strong> coal) <strong>and</strong> for most<br />

small scale decentralised technologies where this occurs by assumption; an exception among<br />

the latter is wind power, where the increased share <strong>of</strong> relatively low wind-speed sites results<br />

in lower overall utilisation; for “middle” load technologies especially those that are gas fired<br />

a significant increase in utilisation seems to have occurred when passing to the constrained<br />

scenario;<br />

- finally the impact on cumulative investments (2000-2030) reflects the degree <strong>of</strong> novelty <strong>of</strong><br />

the technology, the speed <strong>of</strong> its introduction, its technical life, but also the changed<br />

investment <strong>costs</strong> presented above.<br />

The new Marginal Abatement Cost for “Kyoto II” with world flexibility is exhibited in Figure<br />

21. This curve is approximately comparable with the curve <strong>and</strong> equilibrium permit price obtained<br />

with the exogenous technical change version. The results however, especially with regard to the<br />

equilibrium permit price (132.5 $1990 instead <strong>of</strong> 175.4), are sufficiently contrasted to allow an<br />

approximate evaluation <strong>of</strong> the role played by the endogenous technical change mechanism in<br />

reducing the anticipated cost <strong>of</strong> meeting an ambitious CO 2 emission target.<br />

Figure 19<br />

Marginal Abatement Cost <strong>and</strong> “Kyoto II” scenario with endogenous technical<br />

change<br />

Marginal Cost <strong>of</strong> Emission<br />

Reduction<br />

$90/t <strong>of</strong> C<br />

200<br />

180<br />

160<br />

140<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

-10 0 10 20 30 40<br />

World Emission Reductions as % <strong>of</strong> 2030<br />

Reference<br />

Source: POLES model<br />

5 Conclusions<br />

This synthetic presentation <strong>of</strong> the main results <strong>of</strong> the effort performed with the POLES model<br />

only provides a “taste” <strong>of</strong> the type <strong>of</strong> conclusions that can be drawn from this type <strong>of</strong> energy<br />

modelling exercise. It shows first the interest <strong>of</strong> models providing an explicit description <strong>of</strong> the<br />

key energy sector technologies that may play a key role in achieving severe environmental<br />

constraints. It also illustrates the advantages <strong>of</strong> combining a Reference Case, with a full<br />

description <strong>of</strong> a consistent energy system, with alternative cases that explicit the changes <strong>and</strong> the<br />

direct <strong>costs</strong> induced by political decisions on environmental constraints.<br />

133

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!