03.01.2014 Views

sectoral economic costs and benefits of ghg mitigation - IPCC

sectoral economic costs and benefits of ghg mitigation - IPCC

sectoral economic costs and benefits of ghg mitigation - IPCC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Energy Intensive Industries<br />

column, the sector-specific carbon permit prices range from about $160 per ton carbon in the<br />

electric utility sector to around $900 per ton carbon in the transportation sector. These results<br />

reflect the greater ability to fuel-switch in the electric sector on the time horizon to 2010.<br />

Table 4<br />

Carbon Permit Prices in 2010 (1995 US$ per Ton Carbon)<br />

Cases With Trade<br />

With Proportional Cap<br />

Case Price Sector Price<br />

FT 307 AG 423<br />

E/TRG 487 ELEC 157<br />

E/H&AG 504 EINT 402<br />

E/EINT 440 TRAN 881<br />

E/ELEC 913 OIND 386<br />

E/TRAN 452 H 228<br />

The comparison in Table 3 also illustrates one <strong>of</strong> the major <strong>benefits</strong> <strong>of</strong> a trading system. Even<br />

though initial reduction targets by sector might be established in a pattern not too far from<br />

<strong>economic</strong> efficiency, changes in an economy over time will lead these targets to become more<br />

<strong>and</strong> more inefficient. A trade system provides a mechanism that automatically adjusts to<br />

<strong>economic</strong> change (as would a uniform carbon tax). But hard sector targets or technological<br />

requirements are likely to create ever greater distortions, because it is extremely unlikely that<br />

growth in different sectors will be identical or that emissions reduction opportunities will develop<br />

equally across sectors.<br />

The remaining cases all involve exemption <strong>of</strong> one or more sectors, <strong>and</strong> the cost penalties are<br />

correlated with the relative quantities <strong>of</strong> emissions exempted. As shown in Table 3, the cost<br />

penalty in 2010 from exemption <strong>of</strong> these sectors, relative to the case with full trading, ranges<br />

from a low <strong>of</strong> 32% when energy intensive industries are left out (E/EINT) to a high <strong>of</strong> nearly<br />

300% when electricity is omitted from the control regime (E/ELEC). And, similar to the NT<br />

case, the cost penalty associated with each <strong>of</strong> these exemptions grows over the years to 2030.<br />

The penalty rises over time because dem<strong>and</strong> for products from exempted sectors grows as the<br />

prices <strong>of</strong> their goods fall relative to the prices <strong>of</strong> other goods that do bear cost <strong>of</strong> emissions<br />

reductions. Also, at the same time these exempted sectors switch to more carbon intensive fuels<br />

whose prices have fallen because <strong>of</strong> the carbon constraint elsewhere in the U.S. economy (<strong>and</strong> in<br />

other Annex B countries).<br />

Sector Impacts<br />

Another interesting question is whether these exemptions actually have their intended effect. We<br />

are not able to explore this question in detail because, as discussed earlier, we are using a model<br />

that presumes that all assets <strong>and</strong> labor are fully employed. In some policy circles there is concern<br />

about str<strong>and</strong>ed assets - those assets that would be retired prematurely because <strong>of</strong> an<br />

environmental policy. The best way to avoid the severe <strong>economic</strong> loss that str<strong>and</strong>ed assets might<br />

involve is to introduce an economy-wide cap-<strong>and</strong>-trade system, so firms <strong>and</strong> households across<br />

the economy could buy permits rather than retire capital early (Of course, a tight constraint<br />

introduced with little lead-time will cause some capital to be retired prematurely in any case). To<br />

analyze this circumstance would require a model where our exogenous depreciation rate was<br />

replaced with an endogenous representation <strong>of</strong> the retirement decision. Similarly, to capture the<br />

216

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!