28.05.2013 Views

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

ar Ilai, who reported this saying, also drew a line of demarcation<br />

between different types of transport workers. He contended<br />

that “most of the donkey drivers are evildoers, most<br />

of the camel drivers are honest, most of the sailors are pious.”<br />

The latter’s reputation may have been owing to the fact that<br />

*shipping had now become an even more important occupation<br />

than in earlier centuries. The Alexandrian Jewish guild<br />

of navicularii had become so important that even the hostile<br />

Roman administration had to extend it important privileges<br />

in 390 C.E. (Codex Theodosianus, 13, 5, 8).<br />

Perhaps the most significant economic change, resulting<br />

from the transfer of the center of gravity to the dispersion,<br />

occurred in the much larger Jewish participation in<br />

commerce. It is a well-known sociological phenomenon that<br />

alien immigrants often turn to mercantile endeavors because<br />

they have no attachment to the foreign soil, shun isolated living<br />

among native majorities, are familiar with two or more<br />

languages and cultures, and hence are able the better to mediate<br />

between distant localities. If, as seems to have been the<br />

case, a large number of former Phoenicians and Carthaginians<br />

had joined the Jewish community via conversion, they<br />

must have brought some of their commercial skills and contacts<br />

into their new communities. Jewish slaves, if employed<br />

in their masters’ businesses, must also have acquired certain<br />

aptitudes which they put to good use upon obtaining freedom.<br />

For all these reasons the number of Jewish traders, ranging<br />

from peddlers to big merchants, must have greatly increased.<br />

Yet their ratio in the Jewish population of the Diaspora need<br />

not have greatly exceeded the general mercantile ratios among<br />

the majority of peoples.<br />

Even banking began to assume a certain role in Jewish<br />

economic life. True, would-be Jewish moneylenders faced the<br />

tremendous obstacles of the traditional Jewish anti-usury laws.<br />

<strong>In</strong> fact, some rabbis tried, on segregationist grounds, to forbid<br />

their coreligionists to lend money with or without interest<br />

even to gentiles, unless they found absolutely no other means<br />

of earning a living (BM 70b). However, there were always legal<br />

subterfuges which made loans profitable, such as high conventional<br />

fines for missing the repayment date, intervening in<br />

utilization of mortgaged properties, and the like (see, e.g., The<br />

Tebtunis Papyri, 3, 1902, ed. by B.P. Grenfell et al., 315ff., nos.<br />

817–8; E.N. Adler, introd. to his ed. of The Adler Papyri, 1939,<br />

5f.). <strong>In</strong> Alexandria Jewish banking may have played a certain<br />

role even in nurturing the anti-Jewish animus of the population.<br />

This is, at least, the interpretation given by some scholars<br />

to an Alexandrian merchant’s warning to a friend “to beware<br />

of the Jews” recorded in a single papyrus dated 41 C.E. (Aegyptische<br />

Urkunden aus… Berlin, Griechische Urkunden, 2, no.<br />

1079). But this explanation has been cogently disputed. There<br />

is no question, however, that Philo’s relatives, Alexander and<br />

Demetrius, holding the high position of alabarchs (the meaning<br />

of this term is still controversial), could enter banking on<br />

a large scale. For example, Alexander extended to Agrippa I<br />

the substantial loan of 200,000 sesterces (about $30,000), the<br />

bulk of which he paid out to the Jewish king from his Italian<br />

economic history<br />

branch office in Putoli-Dikaerchia (Jos., Ant., 18:160). But<br />

these were exceptions confirming the rule that the majority of<br />

Jews were still very poor and eking out a living by hard work<br />

in various occupations.<br />

On the other hand, in the talmudic age Jewish slavery<br />

played even less of a role than before. Jewish masters, rigidly<br />

circumscribed by law, did not enjoy employing coreligionists<br />

as slaves. A popular adage had it that “he who buys a Hebrew<br />

slave acquires a master unto himself ” (Kid. 20a). Certainly, as<br />

aids in production, even gentile slaves could not compete with<br />

the readily available free laborers. The Roman colonate with<br />

half-free sharecroppers tilling the soil for the landlords only<br />

developed toward the end of antiquity. Characteristically, the<br />

new Christian empire after Constantine I, which totally outlawed<br />

Jewish ownership of Christian slaves and encouraged<br />

pagan slaves to obtain freedom by conversion to Christianity,<br />

was prepared to tolerate the employment of Christian coloni<br />

by Jewish farmers (Gregory I, Epistolae, 4:21, 9:38). Even Jewish<br />

slave trading (see *Slavery and the *Slave Trade), which<br />

was to play a certain role in the early Middle Ages still, was<br />

quite insignificant.<br />

<strong>In</strong> all these activities Jews depended even more than<br />

before on the general economic transformations which took<br />

place during the first centuries of the Christian era. The Roman<br />

Empire’s semicapitalistic economy of the first two centuries<br />

increasingly gave way to a semifeudal system. The Sassanian<br />

Empire never reached the stage of relative economic freedom<br />

of the early Roman Empire. Jews, as well as their intellectual<br />

leaders, had to make constant adjustments to both economic<br />

systems through the adaptation of traditional laws by way of<br />

interpretation. As a consequence of this pliability, rabbinic<br />

legislation was to prove quite useful to the Jewish communities<br />

in their medieval pioneering. One result of the growing<br />

state controls in both empires was a certain regimentation in<br />

occupations and price structures, which also induced the Jews<br />

to organize their own zoning tariffs in transportation, supervision<br />

of weights and measures, and even setting maximum<br />

prices. Even the unfriendly Theodosius I decreed in 396 that<br />

“no one outside the Jewish faith should fix prices for Jews” – a<br />

principle upheld by his successors (Codex Theodosianus, 16, 8,<br />

10). On the other hand, because of the ensuing commercial<br />

restrictions, customs barriers, and innumerable official fees,<br />

the exchanges between the provinces of the Roman Empire<br />

were now severely hampered. This reduction in imperial and<br />

international commerce greatly stimulated the local and regional<br />

autarky and helped to create in many parts of the empire<br />

highly diversified occupational structures, providing for<br />

most of the needs of the local populations. These developments<br />

account also for the greater diversity of occupations<br />

among Jews from the third century onward.<br />

Economically perhaps even more important was the<br />

sharp decline in the class struggle within the Jewish community.<br />

Confronted with indiscriminate hostility on the part of<br />

many neighbors, Jews, whether rich or poor, employers or employees,<br />

had to close ranks. Since the hostile state legislation<br />

ENCYCLOPAEDIA <strong>JUDAICA</strong>, Second Edition, Volume 6 103

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!