28.05.2013 Views

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

economic history<br />

of Castilian Jewry, and Don Isaac b. Judah *Abrabanel. <strong>In</strong> the<br />

early days of the Christian reconquest, the services of able Jewish<br />

financiers and administrators were even more indispensable.<br />

Members of the Cavalleria and Ravaya families were particularly<br />

prominent in 13th-century Aragon. For one example,<br />

Judah b. Labi de la Cavalleria served from 1257 on as bailiff of<br />

Saragossa, from 1260 on as chief treasurer to whom all royal<br />

bailiffs had to submit regular accounts, and finally in 1275 also<br />

as governor of Valencia. Jews were also active in diplomatic<br />

service, for which their familiarity with various lands and<br />

languages made them especially qualified. <strong>In</strong> vain did Pope<br />

Honorius II address a circular letter to the kings of Aragon,<br />

Castile, Navarre, and Portugal, warning them against dispatching<br />

to Muslim courts Jewish envoys who were likely to reveal<br />

state secrets to the Muslim enemies, since “you cannot expect<br />

faithfulness from infidels.” Yet his successor, Gregory IX, generally<br />

even more insistent on the observance of all canonical<br />

provisions, conceded in 1231 and 1239 that the Portuguese and<br />

Hungarian monarchs had no workable alternative.<br />

<strong>In</strong> other countries Jews exerted political influence more<br />

indirectly. Even in some antagonistic German principalities of<br />

the 14th and 15th centuries some Jews were called upon to provide<br />

the necessary funds for raising mercenary forces as well<br />

as to supply them with food, clothing, and other necessities.<br />

Such a combination of large-scale financing and contracting<br />

was performed, for example, by a Jewish banker, Jacob Daniels,<br />

and his son Michael for the archbishop-elector Baldwin of<br />

Trier in 1336–45. This adumbration of the future role of *Court<br />

Jews in helping build up the modern German principality<br />

was cut short, however, by the recurrent waves of intolerance<br />

which swept Germany in the last medieval centuries and resulted<br />

in the expulsion of the Jews from most German areas.<br />

Economic Doctrines<br />

Notwithstanding these constant changes in the Jewish economic<br />

structure and the vital role played by the Jewish economic<br />

contributions for the general society, no ancient or<br />

medieval Jewish scholar devoted himself to the detailed interpretation<br />

of these economic facts and trends. No Jew wrote<br />

economic tracts even of the rather primitive kind current in<br />

Hellenistic and early Muslim letters. All Jewish rationales must<br />

therefore be deduced indirectly from the legal teachings. Even<br />

Maimonides who, in his classification of sciences, recognized<br />

the existence of a branch of science styled domestic economy,<br />

or rather the “government of the household” (a literal translation<br />

of the Greek oikonomia), did not feel prompted to<br />

produce a special monograph on the general or Jewish economic<br />

life. Speaking more broadly of political science which<br />

included that branch of learning, he declared: “On all these<br />

matters philosophers have written books which have been<br />

translated into Arabic, and perhaps those that have not been<br />

translated are even more numerous. But nowadays we no longer<br />

require all this, namely the statutes and laws, since man’s<br />

conduct is [determined] by the divine regulations” (Treatise<br />

on Logic [Millot ha-Higgayon], Arabic text, with Hebrew and<br />

English translations, by Israel Efros, 1937, 18f.). <strong>In</strong> consonance<br />

with this conception, the great codifier devoted the last three<br />

sections of his Mishneh <strong>Torah</strong> to economic matters regulated<br />

by civil law. He also often referred to economic aspects in the<br />

other 11 books, following therein the example of both Bible<br />

and Talmud. None of these normative sources, however, which<br />

always emphasized what ought to be rather than what is or<br />

was, can satisfactorily fill the lacuna created by the absence of<br />

dispassionate analytical, theoretical, and historical economic<br />

studies. From the outset we must, therefore, take account of<br />

the idealistic slant of our entire documentation. The emphasis<br />

upon ethics and psychology far outweighs that of realistic<br />

conceptualism. Only indirectly, through the use of the extant<br />

subsidiary factual source material, can we balance that normative<br />

slant by some realistic considerations.<br />

Typical of such idealistic approaches is the biblical legislation.<br />

For example, the commandment of a year of fallowness<br />

may have resulted from the practical observation that land<br />

under constant cultivation was bound to deteriorate and to<br />

yield progressively less produce. Similar experiences led other<br />

agricultural systems to adopt the rotation of crops and other<br />

methods. But there is no hint to such a realistic objective in<br />

the biblical rationales. The old Book of the Covenant justifies<br />

the commandment by stating that in this way “the poor of<br />

the people may eat” (Ex. 23:11). The more religiously oriented<br />

Book of Leviticus, on the other hand, lays primary stress on<br />

the land keeping “a Sabbath unto the Lord” (25:2) so that it<br />

provide “solemn” rest for servants, foreign settlers, and even<br />

cattle. Similarly, the Jubilee Year was conceived as a measure<br />

of restoring the landed property to the original clan, envisaging<br />

a more or less static agricultural economy, at variance<br />

with the constantly changing realities of the then increasingly<br />

dominant urban group. No less idealistic were the provisions<br />

for the poor, particularly widows and orphans. We also recall<br />

the extremely liberal demand that, upon manumitting his<br />

Hebrew slave, the master should also provide him with some<br />

necessaries for a fresh start in life.<br />

That these and other idealistic postulates did not represent<br />

the living practice in ancient Israel we learn from the reverberating<br />

prophetic denunciations of the oppression of the<br />

poor by the rich and other social disorders. But here again we<br />

deal with even more extravagant idealistic expectations than<br />

had been expressed by the lawgivers. <strong>In</strong> the main, the Bible<br />

reflects in part the “nomadic ideals” carried down from the<br />

patriarchal age and in part the outlook of the subsequently<br />

predominant agricultural population. But the landowning<br />

aristocracy, as well as the priesthood and royal bureaucracy<br />

often residing in Jerusalem and Samaria, and the impact of<br />

foreign relations, especially wars, shaped the actual affairs of<br />

the people to a much larger extent than normative provisions<br />

or prophetic denunciations, although the latter’s long-range<br />

effects far transcended in historic importance the immediate<br />

realities.<br />

Even the far more realistic legal compilations of the<br />

Mishnah, the Talmud, and other rabbinic letters are still in the<br />

114 ENCYCLOPAEDIA <strong>JUDAICA</strong>, Second Edition, Volume 6

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!