28.05.2013 Views

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

ter with her own private funds, as well as garments or jewelry<br />

expressly purchased by the husband for his wife, are clearly<br />

excluded from the levy (ḥM 97:26 and Sma 63).<br />

Plurality of Creditors – Preferential Rights<br />

<strong>In</strong> the case of a written obligation (shetar or deed), the creditor<br />

in whose favor the obligation was first established takes preference<br />

in levying payment on the debtor’s land, whether still<br />

in the latter’s possession (i.e., the free property) or whether<br />

already acquired from the debtor by a third party (i.e., “encumbered<br />

and alienated” property; Ket. 94a; Yad, Malveh,<br />

20:1; Sh. Ar., ḥM 104:1). This preferential right upon recovery<br />

of a debt is the result of an attitude of Jewish law which gives<br />

the creditor, upon the creation of the debt and over and above<br />

his personal right of recourse against the debtor, a lien on the<br />

latter’s land. This lien, which is in the nature of a right, takes<br />

precedence over any similar right acquired by a subsequent<br />

creditor. If a later creditor forestalls an earlier one in levying<br />

on the debtor’s land, some scholars hold that what he succeeds<br />

in recovering cannot be taken from him by an earlier creditor<br />

despite the right of a creditor by deed to seize a debtor’s<br />

“encumbered and alienated” assets – since a later creditor still<br />

takes precedence over a regular purchaser, so that “the door<br />

shall not be bolted before a borrower” (Ket. 94a and Tos. to<br />

ibid.). Other scholars (ibid), followed by the majority of the<br />

posekim (Alfasi and Asheri to Ket. 94a; and Codes), hold that<br />

in these circumstances the levy of the later creditor is not valid<br />

and the earlier creditor may seize from the later one whatever<br />

the later may have recovered. However, if the later creditor<br />

forestalls the earlier one and levies on the beinonit land, but<br />

leaves the debtor with zibburit, the levy will be valid since the<br />

earlier creditor is still able to recover his debt from the zibburit<br />

(Sh. Ar., ḥM 104:1).<br />

So far as the debtor’s chattels are concerned, the earlier<br />

creditor takes no precedence in recovering his debt from such<br />

chattels, since there is no lien over movable property. <strong>In</strong> the<br />

case of two creditors simultaneously claiming the debtor’s<br />

chattels, some scholars hold that the earlier creditor takes precedence<br />

but the majority opinion of the posekim is that there<br />

is no preferential right and the debtor’s assets are shared between<br />

the two creditors (see below; Ket. 94a; and Codes). Even<br />

in respect of land there is no preferential right unless the land<br />

was in the debtor’s possession prior to establishment of the<br />

debt; and if the debtor, at the time the debt was established,<br />

charges in favor of two or more creditors any land which he<br />

may acquire in the future (see *Lien), the earlier creditor will<br />

have no preferential right in respect of such land, since when<br />

the debtor acquires the land it is automatically charged in favor<br />

of both creditors (BB 157b; and Codes).<br />

<strong>In</strong> the case of a mere oral obligation there is no preferential<br />

right between creditors, neither over land nor chattels,<br />

and two creditors seeking to levy payment at the same<br />

time must share the debtor’s property (Rif. Resp. no. 197; see<br />

also Sma to Sh. Ar., ḥM 104 no. 3 and 31). According to some<br />

scholars, however, there is an order of preference in respect<br />

execution<br />

of land in the debtor’s possession (ḥM 104:13 and Sma), even<br />

in the case of oral debt.<br />

The posekim dispute the method of dividing the debtor’s<br />

property amongst his creditors when there is no preferential<br />

right. One opinion is that each creditor takes a share of the<br />

property in proportion to the size of his debt, since it would<br />

be inequitable to divide the property equally in proportion to<br />

the number of creditors (Rabennu Hananel, in Tur ḥM 104:11;<br />

Yad, Malveh 20:4 quoting the Geonim); whereas others hold<br />

that the debtor’s property is shared equally amongst the creditors<br />

according to their number, provided that no creditor receives<br />

more than the due amount of his debt, since the small<br />

creditor is thereby afforded greater protection (Ket. 94a; Alfasi<br />

and Rashi ad loc.; and Codes).<br />

Preferential Rights and <strong>In</strong>solvency<br />

A consequence of the law of preference as described above<br />

is that Jewish law does not recognize some of the laws of insolvency<br />

customary in other legal systems. Thus, it does not<br />

recognize a concurrence with regard to division of an insolvent<br />

estate, whereby all the debtor’s assets – save for those<br />

specifically charged in favor of a particular creditor or creditors<br />

– are divided among his creditors on a concurrent basis<br />

in proportion to the size of each creditor’s claim. Because of<br />

the lien over the debtor’s land afforded in Jewish law to each<br />

of the creditors, the order of precedence in recovering a debt<br />

follows the order of the establishment of the various liens, in<br />

similar manner to the order of preference in other legal systems<br />

regarding specifically charged assets. Even in cases where<br />

there is no prescribed order of preference, for example, in respect<br />

of the debtor’s chattels or land acquired by him after the<br />

establishment of the debt, the assets are distributed amongst<br />

the creditors in proportion to the number of creditors and not<br />

to the size of each claim.<br />

<strong>In</strong> post-talmudic times the law was supplemented, within<br />

the above-mentioned framework, by a number of rules very<br />

similar to the familiar insolvency laws. Some of these rules<br />

were aimed at protecting all the creditors. Thus, for example,<br />

it was laid down that in cases where the law afforded no preferential<br />

right, a proportional share of the debtor’s estate had<br />

to be reserved for those creditors who had not yet claimed<br />

repayment and even for those creditors holding claims that<br />

were not yet due for payment. (Teshuvot Maimoniyyot, Mishp.<br />

no. 41; Rashba, Resp. vol. 1, no. 1111; Keẓot ha-Ḥoshen ḥM 104,<br />

s.s. 2). It also became customary to announce in public that<br />

anyone failing to lodge his claim against a particular insolvent<br />

within a specified period would lose his right (Rashba,<br />

Resp. vol. 1, no. 893).<br />

<strong>In</strong> different periods, when economic crises led to an increase<br />

in cases of insolvency, various takkanot were enacted to<br />

deal with the situation (see Elon, Ḥerut ha-Perat 172ff.). These<br />

provided for the appointment of a trustee (ne’eman) over the<br />

property of an insolvent (a bore’aḥ or “fugitive” as he is called<br />

in the halakhic literature and takkanot of Poland, Germany,<br />

and Lithuania in the 17th and 18th centuries: see Elon, Ḥerut ha-<br />

ENCYCLOPAEDIA <strong>JUDAICA</strong>, Second Edition, Volume 6 595

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!