28.05.2013 Views

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

JUDAICA - Wisdom In Torah

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Methods of tax collection aggravated the generally arbitrary<br />

and unpredictable forms of fiscal exploitation. They were<br />

also designed to demonstrate the taxpayers’ inferiority. A description<br />

preserved in an old papyrus gives an inkling of the<br />

deliberately humiliating ceremony accompanying the delivery<br />

by a representative Jew or Christian of a sum collected from<br />

his community. “Then the emir,” we are told, “gives him a blow<br />

on the neck, and a guard, standing upright before the emir,<br />

drives him roughly away… The public is admitted to enjoy this<br />

show” (J. Karabacek, in Mitteilungen aus der Sammlung der<br />

Papyrus Erzherzog Rainer, 2–3, 1962, 178). Occasionally, following<br />

an old Babylonian custom, the tax receipt was stamped on<br />

the taxpayer’s neck in a more or less indelible form. Needless<br />

to say, the Jews resented such excesses. However, they realized<br />

that their special taxation was the main justification for their<br />

being allowed to live in Muslim countries altogether. A Jewish<br />

family chronicle mentions that the prominent Baghdad Jewish<br />

banker, Netira, on being told by Caliph Al-Mutadid (c. 892)<br />

that the administration wished to eliminate all special Jewish<br />

taxes, allegedly dissuaded the ruler from such drastic action.<br />

He agreed that a reduction of the tax to its original size would<br />

be a blessing for his community, but he added, “Through the<br />

tax the Jew insures his existence. By eliminating it, you would<br />

give free rein to the populace to shed Jewish blood” (A. Harkavy,<br />

in: Festschrift Berliner (1903), 36 (Ar.), 39 (Heb.)). <strong>In</strong> the<br />

back of Netira’s mind may also have loomed the danger that<br />

anyone of Al-Mutadid’s successors might not only reinstate<br />

the taxes but also demand from the Jews the instantaneous<br />

repayment of all arrears thus accrued.<br />

One effect of this discriminatory fiscal pressure was<br />

the constant diminution of the Jewish share in agriculture.<br />

Even after the extension of the land tax to the growing Muslim<br />

majority, many farmers were unable to meet their obligations<br />

to the state. Jewish farmers had the additional burden of<br />

the heavy poll tax paid in produce at a price arbitrarily set by<br />

the tax collector. The requirements of Jewish law, too, particularly<br />

the Sabbath rest commandment, which was much<br />

more stringent than the rest precepts of the Muslim Friday<br />

and Christian Sunday, generally made Jewish agricultural endeavor<br />

less competitive. There is evidence that in the days of<br />

Harun al-Rashid (766–809) the land flight of Palestinian farmers<br />

was so severe that the government was forced to appeal<br />

for their return under the promise of permanent tax abatement.<br />

The chances are that fewer Jews returned after having<br />

found shelter in one or another urban Jewish community. The<br />

growing disorders in the great caliphate from the tenth century<br />

on must also have induced many Jewish villagers, whose<br />

defenselessness invited attacks by marauders, to leave their<br />

landed properties – despite their great attachment to their<br />

ancestral soil attested by some geonic sources – and settle in<br />

a somewhat more secure urban Jewish quarter. Beginning<br />

in the 12th century the increasingly powerful trends toward<br />

semifeudalism throughout the Middle East further militated<br />

against Jewish farming as they did, on a larger scale, in contemporary<br />

Christian Europe.<br />

economic history<br />

On the other hand, new opportunities beckoned to Jews<br />

in the commercial area. The general upsurge of the Middle<br />

East economy during the first centuries of Muslim rule, the<br />

rise of great metropolitan areas such as *Baghdad and *Cairo,<br />

and, for a time, uniformity and stability of currency and relative<br />

security in travel and transportation, all stimulated the<br />

expansion of mercantile activities on the part of merchants<br />

of various nationalities. Commerce was generally held in<br />

higher esteem than agriculture among Middle Eastern Muslims,<br />

Christians, and Jews. Al-*Farabi voiced the prevailing<br />

notions that “villages are in the service of cities.” While in the<br />

internal exchanges within the caliphate the Jews encountered<br />

severe competition on the part of several equally gifted mercantile<br />

groups, including Greeks, Armenians (increasingly<br />

muslimized), Syrians, and even Arabs – a popular Middle<br />

Eastern adage was to state later that one Greek could cheat<br />

two Jews, and one Armenian could cheat two Greeks – Jewish<br />

merchants had certain advantages in domestic and, even<br />

more, in international trade.<br />

<strong>In</strong> the first place their competitors often came from regions<br />

of diverse legal systems. Most of the Christian merchants<br />

followed deep-rooted customs and traditions of the<br />

former provinces of the Byzantine Empire. The Muslims, too,<br />

were divided in their mercantile and other civil laws through<br />

the disparate teachings of their four major schools of Muslim<br />

jurisprudence and the great variations of local and regional<br />

customs. These factors were far less pronounced in the case of<br />

Jews. Although the Babylonian and Palestinian laws often differed<br />

in many significant details, a growing majority of Jews,<br />

settled in the great caliphate and adjoining countries, increasingly<br />

came under the sway of the Babylonian Talmud and its<br />

official interpretation by the geonic academies of Babylonia. At<br />

the same time the presence of Jewish communities throughout<br />

the far-flung empire and in many neighboring countries,<br />

both east and west, assured Jewish merchant travelers a brotherly<br />

reception and help in emergencies wherever they went.<br />

They could also readily establish branch offices, and engage a<br />

number of dependable local agents. Examples like those recorded<br />

in the documents preserved in the Cairo *Genizah<br />

have shown the vast geographic extension of the mercantile<br />

dealings of certain Cairo-Fostat firms. <strong>In</strong> 1115–17 one Abu<br />

ʿImran gave a power of attorney to an agent surnamed “the<br />

candle maker” to look after all his business undertakings in<br />

Sicily, *Morocco, and other localities, as well as to manage his<br />

houses in Spain and Sicily. Another businessman, Ḥalfon b.<br />

Nethanel, after returning to *Aden in 1134 from a prolonged<br />

stay in <strong>In</strong>dia, soon thereafter traveled to Cairo. <strong>In</strong> the following<br />

year we find him in Morocco and *Spain before his return<br />

home (H. Hirschfeld, in: JQR, 16 (1925/26), 280f.; S.D. Goitein,<br />

Speculum, 29 (1954), 186f.)<br />

An even greater advantage accrued to Jewish merchants<br />

in the burgeoning international trade with Western Europe.<br />

Although the Carolingian Empire and its successor states<br />

were still economically quite backward, their growing landed<br />

aristocracy furnished many customers for the luxury articles<br />

ENCYCLOPAEDIA <strong>JUDAICA</strong>, Second Edition, Volume 6 105

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!