06.09.2021 Views

Australian Politics and Policy - Senior, 2019a

Australian Politics and Policy - Senior, 2019a

Australian Politics and Policy - Senior, 2019a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Australian</strong> <strong>Politics</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

pharmaceuticals. Therefore as a quid pro quo for patent protection governments<br />

generally intervene to control prices pharmaceutical firms can charge.<br />

Third, when transactions are covered by insurance – public insurance such as<br />

Medicare or private health insurance through commercial or mutual bodies – there<br />

are incentives for both users <strong>and</strong> providers for overuse. When a service is free or<br />

heavily subsidised at the point of provision, the price signals which act as rationing<br />

mechanisms in most markets are absent. Economists refer to this phenomenon by<br />

the quaint term ‘moral hazard’.<br />

Health economists argue about the extent of moral hazard in health care. Most<br />

(butnotall)healthcareproceduresinvolvesomepainordiscomfort,whichtends<br />

to rule out frivolous dem<strong>and</strong> on the consumer side. And there is evidence that even<br />

modest prices can deter people from using therapeutically necessary services. 12<br />

An enduring debate among health economists has been about the appropriateness<br />

of what is known as ‘fee-for-service’ health care. Fee-for-service care is a<br />

familiar <strong>and</strong> established system of payment, particularly for outpatient services.<br />

In Australia Medicare pays medical practitioners fixed fees for defined items of<br />

service. A common such service is ‘Item 23’ on the Medicare benefits schedule – a<br />

GP consultation of less than 20 minutes.<br />

Some argue that fee-for-service encourages overservicing by practitioners <strong>and</strong><br />

overdependence on health care by patients, suggesting in their place that other<br />

formsofpaymentshouldbeused,suchaswhatisknownas‘capitation’,wherea<br />

medical practitioner or health clinic is paid according to the number of people<br />

in their catchment area (adjusted for age <strong>and</strong> known risk factors). Unsurprisingly<br />

critics of capitation argue that it can provide incentives for under-servicing.<br />

Drivers of health care expenditure<br />

Whichever measure is used – real expenditure per capita or expenditure as a<br />

proportion of GDP – health care expenditure is rising in almost all countries.<br />

During 2003 to 2016 real per-capita health care expenditure growth in OECD<br />

countries averaged 2.4 per cent a year, a rate that would see a doubling every 30<br />

years. 13 Australia’s growth in health care expenditure has been only a little lower. 14<br />

Because governments directly fund a large proportion of health care, <strong>and</strong> try to<br />

control the prices charged by regulated insurers <strong>and</strong> by those with market power,<br />

rising health care expenditure is a significant political concern.<br />

The main driver of expenditure growth is usage, rather than the cost per<br />

service. So long as services are free or heavily subsidised at the point of delivery,<br />

therewillbesomepressureforoveruse.<br />

12 Corscadden et al. 2017.<br />

13 OECD 2017.<br />

14 AIHW 2018b.<br />

612

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!