19.04.2014 Views

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Budget Methods <strong>and</strong> Practices 115<br />

needs <strong>and</strong> highlighting the unavoidability of expenses are well-known<br />

strategies to guard against uncertainty.<br />

In countries where the finance ministry is powerful, has good capacity,<br />

<strong>and</strong> is well organized, ceilings are more rigid. In countries where this is not<br />

the case, ceilings are not taken seriously at all. In both cases, however, the<br />

ceilings are perceived as merely the starting point for the annual budget<br />

struggle. In an incremental system, the informal rules of the game concern<br />

agencies’ strategies to maximize their share in the budget pie, countered by<br />

the ministry of finance’s strategies to bring requests down to manageable<br />

numbers <strong>and</strong> size.<br />

A classical strategy of agencies is to pad their requests on the assumption<br />

that the ministry of finance is likely to effect cuts as a matter of course.<br />

Estimates are rarely prepared well, with the result that the ministry of<br />

finance, lacking sufficient information <strong>and</strong>, often, sufficient capacity to cut<br />

in a refined manner, resorts to percentage decreases across spending agency<br />

budgets. Budgets then are effectively made at the center, with little spending<br />

agency input.<br />

Wildavsky <strong>and</strong> Caiden (1980: 141) note that in an incremental system<br />

with ritualistic cycles of padding <strong>and</strong> cutting, spending agencies that do not<br />

leave room for cuts disconcert their examiners. The larger the request <strong>and</strong><br />

the number of proposals, the more the ministry of finance can cut while still<br />

giving a department additions to its previous total. A department that submits<br />

a high number of projects is at an advantage, because it is likely to<br />

receive more.<br />

Agencies with superior information also routinely underbudget for<br />

high-priority expenditure or for expenditure driven by legislative requirements.<br />

During the spending year, ministries of finance have little choice but<br />

to provide provisional funding to cover shortfalls. Another version of asking<br />

for less than what is required occurs when spending agencies in an annual<br />

budget system provide low first-year estimates of project costs. Once the<br />

project is approved, future-year expenses are much higher, with the government<br />

committed to finish what it has started.<br />

The difference between industrial <strong>and</strong> developing countries, however,<br />

does not lie in the existence of practices such as these, but rather in how<br />

frequently they occur <strong>and</strong> how extreme they are (Wildavsky <strong>and</strong> Caiden 1980:<br />

142). The stable environment of industrial countries means that it is less<br />

necessary for spending agencies to inflate their requests over the previous<br />

year’s totals to ensure that they hold on to funds. Finance ministries in industrial<br />

countries usually also have more accurate information on what is being<br />

spent <strong>and</strong> what is required to fulfill policy commitments, thereby putting

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!