19.04.2014 Views

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Deficit Elimination Rules<br />

Accrual Accounting in the <strong>Public</strong> <strong>Sector</strong> 193<br />

What are the effects of different accounting regimes if fiscal authorities want<br />

to eliminate an existing deficit but are unconstrained with respect to the level<br />

of public capital? Assume that authorities begin with a deficit <strong>and</strong> commit to<br />

reduce it smoothly so that it is eliminated by a specified future date. Subject<br />

to the deficit elimination constraint, assume that authorities’ objective is to<br />

maximize operating spending.<br />

In any given period, authorities must choose between providing transfers<br />

or investing in additional capital. Whether they operate under a cash or<br />

an accrual accounting regime, authorities’ optimal strategy is to concentrate<br />

incremental spending on transfers. The reason is that under both regimes<br />

their deficit target requires that they forgo transfers in the current period to<br />

create cash to finance investment. Although the capital stock declines in an<br />

equivalent manner under both regimes, the debt trajectories <strong>and</strong> mix of<br />

spending over time differ. Under accrual accounting, the cash generated by<br />

amortization is used to reduce debt, whereas under cash accounting all revenue<br />

not allocated to services <strong>and</strong> debt payments can be spent on transfers. Thus,<br />

under cash accounting, transfer spending is higher.<br />

The policy implication of this analysis is that a fiscal consolidation program<br />

is less stringent under cash accounting than under accrual. The reason<br />

is that under cash accounting, authorities are able “finance” a portion of the<br />

adjustment through unrecorded depreciation of capital. Or put another way,<br />

a cash deficit is easier to eliminate than an accrual deficit. Whether such a<br />

strategy is desirable depends on one’s perspective. For policy makers searching<br />

for the least politically costly way of eliminating a structural deficit, cash<br />

accounting may be preferable—especially if the period of adjustment is relatively<br />

short <strong>and</strong> the resulting decline in public sector capital is manageable.<br />

Of course, it may be that fiscal authorities, especially those who have<br />

achieved fiscal balance, have objectives other than maximizing operating<br />

spending. For example, it may be that authorities wish to maximize capital<br />

accumulation because of the particular political benefits that flow from public<br />

investment. Next, consider how authorities with these alternative objectives<br />

behave under the cash <strong>and</strong> accrual accounting regimes.<br />

Constrained only to avoid deficits, the investment-maximizing government<br />

would simply eliminate all transfer spending. To avoid this unrealistic<br />

outcome, impose the additional constraint that transfer spending cannot be<br />

reduced below its initial value. For the government facing these two constraints,<br />

the optimal strategy under both accounting regimes is to hold<br />

transfers constant <strong>and</strong> to devote all revenue in excess of that needed to fund<br />

the operation of existing capital <strong>and</strong> debt service to new investment.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!