19.04.2014 Views

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

426 Salvatore Schiavo-Campo<br />

By Objectives or by Results?<br />

The classic approach to evaluation (assess the degree of achievement of the<br />

objectives stated at inception of the task) <strong>and</strong> the pragmatic approach (assess<br />

the results actually achieved, whether or not they match the initial objectives)<br />

do not necessarily produce the same verdict. The classic approach has been<br />

criticized for lending itself to excessive formalism <strong>and</strong> enabling a mutation<br />

of simple <strong>and</strong> useful ideas into monsters of red tape. 18 But because M&E<br />

capacity takes time to build, the pragmatic approach can degrade into an<br />

alibi for perennial postponement of reckoning <strong>and</strong> accountability. On balance,<br />

it is probably preferable to adopt the classic approach of evaluation by objectives<br />

but complement it with some form of midcourse assessments. Thus,<br />

evaluation shades into supervision.<br />

In-house or External M&E Capacity?<br />

The st<strong>and</strong>ard assumption is that M&E capacity should be created within the<br />

government itself. Regardless of whether this assumption is correct, it is<br />

surely fallacious to assume that because evaluation of government activities<br />

is important it must be conducted by government. In-house evaluation has<br />

the obvious advantage of inside expertise, savvy, <strong>and</strong> intimate operational<br />

knowledge of the programs being evaluated (as in Australia). The other side<br />

of the coin is a natural tendency to overstate results, <strong>and</strong>, where accountability<br />

systems are weak or nonexistent, even to provide a coat of whitewash<br />

to failed programs. 19 The advantages of external evaluation are, first, its<br />

presumptively stronger independence <strong>and</strong>, second, the greater probability<br />

that the evaluators are familiar with similar programs in other sectors or<br />

other countries. 20<br />

These advantages are not exclusive, however. In-house government evaluation<br />

organs can also be assured of a degree of independence close to that<br />

enjoyed by external entities. Conversely, if external evaluators contribute on<br />

a regular basis, they will develop the intimate underst<strong>and</strong>ing of operations<br />

that is needed for an informed assessment. The disadvantages, too, are not<br />

exclusive: in particular, if the governance climate is not conducive to c<strong>and</strong>id<br />

evaluations, most probably even the best external evaluations will be suppressed<br />

or distorted to produce the desired results. The choice is entirely<br />

pragmatic. Thorough evaluations require a substantial input by economists,<br />

researchers, <strong>and</strong> auditors—skills that are in limited supply in African developing<br />

countries <strong>and</strong> are best used in designing <strong>and</strong> running sound programs,<br />

not in evaluating them. Thus, evaluation in developing countries inevitably

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!