19.04.2014 Views

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Budget Preparation <strong>and</strong> Approval 249<br />

current expenditures. Given the macroeconomic <strong>and</strong> fiscal forecasts <strong>and</strong><br />

objectives, the resources allocated to public investment have typically been<br />

a residual, estimated by deducting recurrent expenditure needs from the<br />

expected amount of revenues (given the overall deficit target). The residual<br />

character of the domestic funding of development expenditures may even<br />

be aggravated during the process of budget execution, when urgent current<br />

spending preempts investment spending—which can be postponed more<br />

easily. In such a situation, dual budgeting yields the opposite problem:<br />

unmet domestic investment needs <strong>and</strong> insufficient counterpart funds for<br />

good projects financed on favorable external terms. Insufficient aggregate<br />

provision of local counterpart funds (which is itself a symptom of a bad<br />

investment budgeting process) is a major source of waste of resources.<br />

Certainly, investment budgeting is submitted to strong pressures because<br />

of particular or regional interest (the so-called pork barrel projects) <strong>and</strong><br />

because it gives more opportunities for corruption than current expenditures.<br />

In countries with poor governance, vested interests may favor keeping separate<br />

the process of preparing the investment budget, <strong>and</strong> thus a tendency exists to<br />

increase public investment spending. However, under those circumstances,<br />

to concentrate power <strong>and</strong> bribery opportunities in the h<strong>and</strong>s of a powerful<br />

unified-budget baron would hardly improve expenditure management or<br />

reduce corruption. On the contrary, it is precisely in these countries that<br />

focusing first on improving the integrity of the separate investment programming<br />

process may be the only way to ensure that some resources are<br />

allocated to economically sound projects <strong>and</strong> to improve over time the<br />

budget process as a whole. The appropriate organizational decisions will<br />

come at a later stage.<br />

Recall that the real issue is lack of integration between investment <strong>and</strong><br />

current expenditure programming <strong>and</strong> not the separate processes in themselves.<br />

This fact is important, because to misidentify the issue would lead<br />

(<strong>and</strong> often has led) to considering the problem solved by a simple merger<br />

of two ministries—even while coordination remains just as weak. A former<br />

minister becomes a deputy minister, organizational “boxes” are reshuffled,<br />

a few people are promoted, <strong>and</strong> others are demoted. But dual budgeting<br />

remains alive <strong>and</strong> well within the bosom of the umbrella ministry. Instead,<br />

when coordination between two initially separate processes is close <strong>and</strong><br />

iteration is effective, the two budgets end up consistent with each other <strong>and</strong><br />

with government policies, <strong>and</strong> dual budgeting is no great problem. Thus,<br />

when the current <strong>and</strong> investment budget processes are separate, whether<br />

they should be brought under the same roof depends on the institutional<br />

characteristics of the country. In countries where the agency responsible for

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!