19.04.2014 Views

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series: Budgeting and ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

258 Salvatore Schiavo-Campo<br />

In other countries, such as the United Kingdom, the projections are validated<br />

by the independent auditor general. In most African developing countries,<br />

the macroeconomic <strong>and</strong> fiscal projections are developed with the support<br />

of external organizations, which gives them a measure of added credibility.<br />

In some countries, such as Tanzania, this cooperation has become close<br />

enough to make the formulation of these frameworks a virtual partnership<br />

(albeit without infringing on the country’s sovereign authority to make its<br />

own decisions).<br />

A major issue in this regard is whether to adopt binding rules on fiscal<br />

outcomes (for example, a prescribed level of deficit) or behavior (for<br />

example, prohibition against borrowing except for investment spending).<br />

This issue, often going under the name of fiscal responsibility, is briefly<br />

discussed below.<br />

Whose “fiscal responsibility”?<br />

Several countries have laws <strong>and</strong> rules that restrict the fiscal policy of government<br />

<strong>and</strong> prescribe fiscal outcomes. 6 For example, the so-called golden<br />

rule stipulates that public borrowing must not exceed investment (thus in<br />

fact prescribing a current budget balance or surplus, as in Germany). In<br />

many federal countries, the budget of subnational government entities must<br />

be balanced by law. In the European Union (EU), the Maastricht Treaty stipulated<br />

specific fiscal convergence criteria, concerning both the ratio of the<br />

fiscal deficit to GDP <strong>and</strong> the debt-to-GDP ratio. (The former criterion has<br />

been by far the more important.) EU member countries whose fiscal deficit<br />

is higher than the permitted 3 percent of GDP limit are, supposedly, liable<br />

for large penalties. Box 8.3 summarizes similar arrangements in countries of<br />

the West African Economic <strong>and</strong> Monetary Union.<br />

A frequent criticism of such rules is that they favor creative accounting<br />

<strong>and</strong> encourage nontransparent fiscal practices by burying expenditures<br />

or listing as regular revenue one-off revenues. Also, when the rules are<br />

effectively enforced, the criticism is that they can prevent governments<br />

from adjusting their budgets to the economic cycle, thus making worse<br />

both recessions <strong>and</strong> inflationary pressures. The European experience has,<br />

unfortunately, also shown that the Maastricht rules are selectively<br />

enforced, with no penalties exacted for violation by the largest <strong>and</strong> most<br />

important EU members.<br />

In contrast with an approach based on rigid targets, other countries<br />

(for example, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>) do not m<strong>and</strong>ate specific fiscal targets but refer<br />

to criteria such as prudent levels <strong>and</strong> reasonable degrees. The government<br />

is left to specify the targets in a budget policy statement, which presents

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!