22.12.2012 Views

Collected Works of V. I. Lenin - Vol. 3 - From Marx to Mao

Collected Works of V. I. Lenin - Vol. 3 - From Marx to Mao

Collected Works of V. I. Lenin - Vol. 3 - From Marx to Mao

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

256<br />

V. I. LENIN<br />

But before examining the data for the separate areas,<br />

let us note the following: the Narodnik economists, as we<br />

have seen, do all they can <strong>to</strong> evade the fact that the characteristic<br />

feature <strong>of</strong> the post-Reform period is the growth <strong>of</strong><br />

commercial agriculture. Naturally, in doing so they also<br />

ignore the circumstance that the drop in grain prices is<br />

bound <strong>to</strong> stimulate the specialisation <strong>of</strong> agriculture and the<br />

drawing <strong>of</strong> agricultural produce in<strong>to</strong> the sphere <strong>of</strong> exchange.<br />

Here is an instance. The authors <strong>of</strong> the well-known book<br />

The Influence <strong>of</strong> Harvests and Grain Prices all proceed from<br />

the postulate that the price <strong>of</strong> grain is <strong>of</strong> no importance <strong>to</strong><br />

natural economy, and they repeat this “truism” endlessly.<br />

One <strong>of</strong> them, Mr. Kablukov, has observed, however, that<br />

under the general conditions <strong>of</strong> commodity production this<br />

postulate is substantially wrong. “It is possible, <strong>of</strong> course,”<br />

he writes, “that the grain placed on the market has cost less<br />

<strong>to</strong> produce than that grown on the consumer’s farm, in<br />

which case it would appear <strong>to</strong> be in the interest also <strong>of</strong> the<br />

consuming farm <strong>to</strong> change from cultivating cereals <strong>to</strong> other<br />

crops” (or <strong>to</strong> other occupations, we would add), “and,<br />

consequently, for it <strong>to</strong>o the market price <strong>of</strong> grain assumes<br />

importance as soon as it fails <strong>to</strong> coincide with its cost <strong>of</strong><br />

production” (I, 98, note, author’s italics). “But we cannot<br />

take that in<strong>to</strong> account,” he says peremp<strong>to</strong>rily. Why is that?<br />

Because, it seems: 1) a change-over <strong>to</strong> other crops is possible<br />

“only where certain conditions exist.” By means <strong>of</strong> this<br />

empty truism (everything on earth is possible only under certain<br />

conditions!) Mr. Kablukov calmly evades the fact that<br />

the post-Reform period in Russia has created, and continues<br />

<strong>to</strong> create, the very conditions that call for<br />

the specialisation <strong>of</strong> agriculture and the diversion <strong>of</strong><br />

the population from agriculture. . . . 2) Because “in our<br />

climate it is impossible <strong>to</strong> find a crop equal <strong>to</strong> cereals in food<br />

value”. The argument is highly original, expressing a mere<br />

evasion <strong>of</strong> the issue. What has the food value <strong>of</strong> other crops<br />

<strong>to</strong> do with the matter, if we are dealing with the sale <strong>of</strong><br />

these other crops and the purchase <strong>of</strong> cheap grain? . . .<br />

3) Because “grain farms <strong>of</strong> the consuming type always have a<br />

rational basis for their existence.” In other words, because<br />

Mr. Kablukov “and colleagues” regard natural economy as<br />

“rational.” The argument, as you see, is irrefutable. . . .

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!