02.03.2013 Views

Thinking and Deciding

Thinking and Deciding

Thinking and Deciding

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

500 RISK<br />

Torts<br />

A fourth mechanism is the tort system: lawsuits. When a person is injured because of<br />

someone else’s risk-producing activity, the victim can sue the injurer. Such lawsuits<br />

work much like pollution taxes. They give potential injurers an incentive to reduce<br />

risks to others. The incentive is reduced risk of lawsuits. Being found liable sends<br />

a message to those in the position of the injurer (including the injurer) to take care<br />

because they will be held responsible for the consequences of their recklessness.<br />

A variety of principles govern tort law, <strong>and</strong> these principles vary from region to<br />

region. One common principle is ”negligence.” The injurer must pay only if the<br />

injurer takes insufficient care. In a classic case in U.S. law, Judge Learned H<strong>and</strong><br />

ruled that Carroll Towing Co. was liable for damages caused by one of its barges<br />

breaking loose from its mooring <strong>and</strong> running into a ship. H<strong>and</strong> argued that the owner<br />

of the barge was negligent if the burden of precautions was less than the probability<br />

of harm times the gravity of the injury, that is, the expected loss from not taking a<br />

certain amount of care (L<strong>and</strong>es <strong>and</strong> Posner, 1987). In this case, the care at issue was<br />

having an attendant on board the barge (which was not common practice at the time).<br />

If such a precaution could be taken <strong>and</strong> lead to a total net saving, then the amount of<br />

care being taken was less than the optimum. The net saving is the cost of the losses<br />

prevented, minus the cost of the radios. Another st<strong>and</strong>ard, more rarely applied, is<br />

“strict liability.” By this st<strong>and</strong>ard, the injurer pay for any damages, regardless of the<br />

amount of care that was taken.<br />

One issue that often arises in tort law is “who is responsible?” A recent example<br />

is the litigation in the United States concerning the risk of cigarettes. The cigarette<br />

makers claim that smokers are themselves responsible, so the companies should not<br />

have to pay for the harm caused by their products. A simpler example is the case<br />

of someone who falls off a ladder as a result of positioning the ladder upside down.<br />

Should the company be required to put a “this end up” label on the ladder or to make<br />

it impossible to put the ladder the wrong way?<br />

From a normative economic point of view, this issue hinges on the question of<br />

who can reduce the risk most efficiently, what Calabresi (1960) called the “least cost<br />

avoider.” If the law makes the companies pay to reduce the risk, <strong>and</strong> if individuals<br />

could reduce the risk more cheaply, then the payment is inefficient. The extra cost required<br />

to avoid losing lawsuits will raise the price of the product, forcing consumers<br />

to pay more or do without it. It would be better not to make the company pay. Of<br />

course, the question of who is the least-cost avoider depends on what the next step<br />

is. A warning label would be inexpensive. A device to make sure that ladders cannot<br />

be used upside down might be more expensive <strong>and</strong> not worth the cost.<br />

Compensation<br />

Tort law has a second function which is compensation of victims. Compensation<br />

<strong>and</strong> incentive are different functions. Compensation, in the form of money, provides<br />

resources to those who can put them to good use to recover their way of life — for

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!