02.03.2013 Views

Thinking and Deciding

Thinking and Deciding

Thinking and Deciding

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

MENTAL ACCOUNTING 301<br />

When we evaluate outcomes, we often look for points of comparison, or “norms,”<br />

even when no decision was involved. Our reactions depend on the comparison that<br />

comes to mind most easily. Consider the following case (from Kahneman <strong>and</strong> Tversky,<br />

1982b):<br />

Mr. C <strong>and</strong> Mr. D were scheduled to leave the airport on different flights,<br />

at the same time. They traveled from town in the same limousine, were<br />

caught in a traffic jam, <strong>and</strong> arrived at the airport 30 minutes after the<br />

scheduled departure time of their flights. Mr. D is told that his flight left<br />

on time. Mr. C is told that his flight was delayed, <strong>and</strong> left only 5 minutes<br />

ago. Who is more upset?<br />

Most people agree that Mr. C is more upset. It is easier for Mr. C to imagine how<br />

things could have been otherwise. These mental simulations of alternative outcomes<br />

function as reference points to which the real outcome is compared.<br />

Opportunity costs<br />

Economists <strong>and</strong> accountants use the term “opportunity cost” to refer to the benefit of<br />

a forgone option relative to the status quo. Consider two business ventures. Both cost<br />

$10,000. Venture A is expected to return $11,000 in a year. Venture B is expected<br />

to return $11,500 in a year. Venture B uses some materials that you already own,<br />

which you could sell for $1,000 if you don’t use them. It is tempting to decide in<br />

favor of venture B because it yields a larger profit, <strong>and</strong> many people do indeed make<br />

this choice (Becker, Ronen, <strong>and</strong> Sorter, 1974). But this is a mistake. Venture B<br />

will “cost” an additional $1,000 because the materials cannot be sold. This is the<br />

opportunity cost. We can also think of this as a benefit of A: If we undertake A, we<br />

gain an additional $1,000 from selling the materials. It does not matter how we think<br />

of it: Venture A is still better.<br />

It is easy to neglect opportunity costs when considering whether to make a transaction<br />

or do nothing. For example, suppose that you are buying a car <strong>and</strong> you are<br />

offered a low-interest loan. If you have sufficient cash to buy the car outright, you<br />

may reject the loan, thinking, “Why should I pay interest if I don’t have to?” But if<br />

you spend your cash, you also lose the interest that you could make by investing that<br />

cash. If the investment interest is higher than the interest you must pay on the loan,<br />

then you should take the loan. (In real life, the decision is more complex because<br />

of taxes.) In making decisions like this, it is often useful to focus on the differences<br />

between the options rather than on the gains or losses of one option relative to a<br />

reference point.<br />

Positive <strong>and</strong> negative attributes<br />

We sometimes think of decisions negatively as dilemmas in which we must choose<br />

the lesser evil, as when we must choose between two unpleasant medical treatments.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!