02.03.2013 Views

Thinking and Deciding

Thinking and Deciding

Thinking and Deciding

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

456 SOCIAL DILEMMAS: COOPERATION VERSUS DEFECTION<br />

versa. To manipulate expectations about others, subjects were told after the first trial<br />

that the pool contained either 380 or 120 units.<br />

In the give-some game, subjects gave less on subsequent trials when they thought<br />

that the pool contained 380 after the first trial than when they thought it had 120.<br />

That is, behavior was opposite from what others were perceived as doing. In the<br />

take-some game, they took less when they thought that the pool had 380. Behavior<br />

was the same as what others were perceived as doing. Evidently, give-some subjects<br />

reasoned, “If nobody else is giving anything, then I’d better do it, but if others are<br />

giving a lot, I can take advantage of them.” (Formally, this is what we have been<br />

calling greed.) Take-some subjects seemed to reason, “If nobody else is taking, then<br />

I’d better not take either, but if others are taking, then I can take too.” What we<br />

have been calling “fear” seems to operate to prevent harmful actions but not harmful<br />

omissions. (These effects were small <strong>and</strong> should be replicated, but they help to make<br />

sense out of previous conflicting results.)<br />

It is clear that, in many cases, people are sensitive to the behavior of others <strong>and</strong><br />

will do what they expect others to do. Researchers have proposed several explanations<br />

of this tendency. One is fear, as just noted, although this may be balanced by<br />

greed.<br />

Another closely related motive is fairness. People do not want to be treated<br />

unfairly by others who defect when they cooperate, nor do they want to treat others<br />

unfairly by defecting when others cooperate.<br />

Another motive is reciprocity. People want to “get back” at those who defect by<br />

defecting themselves: They will pay to punish defectors (Fehr <strong>and</strong> Gächter, 2000).<br />

People may also simply conform. Evidence of this is that they are influenced by<br />

the behavior of others playing the same social dilemma but in a different group, so<br />

that reciprocity is impossible (Bardsley <strong>and</strong> Sausgruber, 2005).<br />

Finally, <strong>and</strong> more generally, people seem sensitive to social norms. They respond<br />

to the expectations of others that norms of cooperation should be followed, <strong>and</strong> they<br />

support those norms even at some cost to themselves (p. 395).<br />

Tyran (2004) did a study in which subjects could contribute real money (from<br />

the experimental payment) to a charity. In all conditions, contributions to the charity<br />

were decided by vote. The experimental conditions varied in the number of votes<br />

required for the contributions to be made, <strong>and</strong> (if so) in whether “no” voters had to<br />

contribute or not. If no-votes did have to contribute, then the effect of a subject’s<br />

vote on whether the subject had to contribute was small; the vote determined your<br />

contribution only if it was pivotal.<br />

Voting in favor did not depend on whether no-votes had to contribute, but they<br />

increased as a function of the subject’s expectation that the proposal would be approved.<br />

Evidently, subjects wanted to do their part if others voted for contributing.<br />

It seemed that they were responding to a social norm. Most importantly, subjects<br />

ignored the effect of their vote on the outcome for themselves.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!