02.03.2013 Views

Thinking and Deciding

Thinking and Deciding

Thinking and Deciding

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

BAD REASONS FOR STICKING TO PLANS: BIASES 477<br />

they had $10 million to invest <strong>and</strong> were asked to decide which of two divisions of the<br />

business they would invest it in for research <strong>and</strong> development. Half of these students<br />

were told that the division they had chosen did well after the investment; half were<br />

told it did badly. They were then asked to divide an additional $20 million between<br />

the two divisions. When the chosen division had performed badly, the allocation to<br />

that division the second time around averaged about $13 million (out of $20 million),<br />

but when the division had done well the allocation averaged only about $9 million.<br />

Other subjects were not asked to make the original decision on the investment<br />

of the $10 million; they were told that it had been made by someone else. These<br />

subjects allocated about $8 million to the division that had received the $10 million<br />

when they were told that the division had done well, <strong>and</strong> they allocated about the<br />

same amount of money when they were told it had done badly. In short, subjects<br />

allocated extra money to the division that had previously received $10 million only<br />

when they had decided to allocate the original $10 million <strong>and</strong> when the division<br />

in question did badly. Presumably this was caused by a desire to believe that their<br />

original decision had been a good one, leading to a belief that the original decision<br />

had been a good one, leading to additional investment in a cause that seemed likely<br />

to succeed (see Chapter 12). 1<br />

In sum, the status quo bias, omission bias, the sunk-cost effect, <strong>and</strong> the commitment<br />

effect can cause us to stick to our plans, even when the rational reasons listed in<br />

the preceding section are not sufficient to keep us from switching, given the greater<br />

expected future benefits of a new course. We may stick to our old course because<br />

we feel that we have sunk too much into it to give it up — even though putting more<br />

into it will only increase the waste. Likewise, by analogy with the endowment effect,<br />

we may feel that the loss of the advantages of our current course outweighs the gain<br />

from switching to a new course, although we would choose the new course if we<br />

looked at the whole situation afresh.<br />

Sometimes we stick to plans irrationally because of our basic aversion to risks,<br />

resulting from the certainty effect (Chapter 11). Our present course seems to us to<br />

have consequences known with certainty. However (as argued in Chapter 11), this<br />

may be an illusion resulting from our failure to consider the true variability of the<br />

consequences that might result from our present course.<br />

Finally, a major change of plans, especially when it involves a change of goals,<br />

may seem to a person to involve a loss of self, a partial death in which some of the self<br />

is replaced with a different person. A change of this sort creates a sense of personal<br />

loss that may not be easily compensated for by the creation of a new person inside<br />

one’s skin. The fear of such a loss may be irrational if the new person is otherwise<br />

to be preferred (see Parfit, 1984).<br />

1 The same results are found when the decision involves hiring people who perform either well or<br />

badly (Bazerman, Beekun, <strong>and</strong> Schoorman, 1982) <strong>and</strong> when the decisions are made by groups instead of<br />

individuals (Bazerman, Giuliano, <strong>and</strong> Appleman, 1984).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!