25.06.2013 Views

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

A Corcos <strong>et</strong> al Q UANTITATIVE F INANCE<br />

p t<br />

p t<br />

p t<br />

0.5<br />

0.0<br />

–0.5<br />

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10<br />

2.5<br />

2.0<br />

1.5<br />

1.0<br />

0.5<br />

0.0<br />

t<br />

0 1 2 3 4 5<br />

t<br />

6 7 8 9 10<br />

10 1<br />

10 0<br />

10 –1<br />

0 1 2 3 4 5<br />

t<br />

6 7 8 9 10<br />

Figure 20. Upper panel: r<strong>et</strong>urn trajectory ˜rt = γ ˜pt − 1/2 for<br />

m = 100, N = 100, ρhb = ρbh = 0.72 and ρhh = ρbb = 0.85 and<br />

γ = 0.01. Middle panel: price trajectory obtained by<br />

πt = πt−1 exp[˜rt]. Lower panel: same as the middle panel with πt<br />

shown on a logarithmic scale. Note the ‘fl<strong>at</strong> trough–sharp peak’<br />

structure of the log-price trajectory (Roehner and Sorn<strong>et</strong>te 1998).<br />

the combin<strong>at</strong>ion of mim<strong>et</strong>ic and antagonistic behaviour in the<br />

form<strong>at</strong>ion of expect<strong>at</strong>ions about prices.<br />

The specific fe<strong>at</strong>ure of the mo<strong>de</strong>l is to combine these two<br />

Keynesian aspects of specul<strong>at</strong>ion and enterprise and to <strong>de</strong>rive<br />

from them behavioural rules based on collective opinion: the<br />

agents can adopt an imit<strong>at</strong>ive and gregarious behaviour or,<br />

on the contrary, anticip<strong>at</strong>e a reversal of ten<strong>de</strong>ncy, thereby<br />

d<strong>et</strong>aching themselves from the current trend. It is this duality,<br />

the continuous coexistence of these two elements, which is <strong>at</strong><br />

the origin of the properties of our mo<strong>de</strong>l: chaotic behaviour<br />

and the gener<strong>at</strong>ion of bubbles.<br />

It is a common wisdom th<strong>at</strong> d<strong>et</strong>erministic chaos leads to<br />

fundamental limits of predictability because the tiny inevitable<br />

fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions in those chaotic systems quickly snowball in<br />

unpredictable ways. This has been investig<strong>at</strong>ed in rel<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

to, for instance, long-term we<strong>at</strong>her p<strong>at</strong>terns. However, in<br />

the context of our mo<strong>de</strong>ls, we have shown th<strong>at</strong> the chaotic<br />

dynamics of the r<strong>et</strong>urns alone cannot be the limiting factor<br />

for predictability, as it contains too many residual correl<strong>at</strong>ions.<br />

Endogenous fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions due to finite-size effects and external<br />

news (noise) seem to be nee<strong>de</strong>d as important factors leading to<br />

the observed randomness of stock mark<strong>et</strong> prices. The rel<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

b<strong>et</strong>ween these extrinsic factors and the intrinsic ones studied<br />

in this paper will be explored elsewhere.<br />

Remarks and acknowledgements<br />

This paper is an outgrowth and extension of unpublished work<br />

(1994) by three of us (AC, JPE, AM) which was in turn based<br />

on the PhD of Anne Corcos in 1993. We are gr<strong>at</strong>eful to<br />

J V An<strong>de</strong>rsen for useful discussions. This work was partially<br />

supported by the Fonds N<strong>at</strong>ional Suisse (JPE and AM) and<br />

278<br />

Figure 21. Evolution of the system over 10 000 time steps for<br />

m = 60 polled agents with (upper panel) N =∞, (second panel)<br />

N = m +1= 61 and param<strong>et</strong>ers ρhb = ρbh = 0.72 and<br />

ρhh = ρbb = 0.85. The lower panel represents the ‘noise’<br />

introduced by the finite size of the system and is obtained by<br />

subtracting the upper panel from the second panel.<br />

175<br />

by the James S Mc Donnell Found<strong>at</strong>ion 21st century scientist<br />

award/studying complex system (DS).<br />

Appendix<br />

We expand Fm(p) around the fixed point p = 1/2, so th<strong>at</strong>,<br />

using the symm<strong>et</strong>ry of Fm(p)<br />

Fm(p) = 1<br />

2 +F ′ m<br />

1<br />

(1/2)(p− 2<br />

(3)<br />

1<br />

)+F m (1/2)(p− 2 )3 +···. (29)<br />

First of all, it is obvious to show by recursion th<strong>at</strong><br />

F ′ m (1/2) = 1 − 2gm(1/2) − g ′ m (1/2)<br />

F<br />

(30)<br />

(2k+1)<br />

m (1/2) =−2(2k +1)g (2k)<br />

m (1/2)<br />

− g (2k+1)<br />

m (1/2) if k>0. (31)<br />

The problem thus amounts to calcul<strong>at</strong>ing the <strong>de</strong>riv<strong>at</strong>ives of gm.<br />

Some simple algebraic manipul<strong>at</strong>ions allow us to obtain<br />

g ′ m−1 <br />

<br />

m − 1<br />

m (p) = m<br />

p<br />

j<br />

j=0<br />

m1−j (1 − p) j<br />

<br />

j j +1<br />

× f − f<br />

m m<br />

m−1 <br />

<br />

m − 1<br />

=−m<br />

p<br />

j<br />

j=0<br />

(32)<br />

m1−j (1 − p) j 1fm(j), (33)<br />

where 1fm(·) is the first-or<strong>de</strong>r discr<strong>et</strong>e <strong>de</strong>riv<strong>at</strong>ive of f( ·<br />

m ),<br />

which yields<br />

<br />

1<br />

=−<br />

2<br />

m<br />

2m−1 m−1 <br />

<br />

m − 1<br />

1fm(j). (34)<br />

j<br />

g ′ m<br />

j=0

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!