25.06.2013 Views

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

2.2. Des bulles r<strong>at</strong>ionnelles aux krachs 51<br />

48 D. Sorn<strong>et</strong>te, Y. Malevergne / Physica A 299 (2001) 40–59<br />

imposes EQ[bt]=EQ[ct]=0 and EQ[<strong>at</strong>]=EQ[dt]= −1 . We are going to r<strong>et</strong>rieve this<br />

result more formally in the general case.<br />

3.2. General formul<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

A generaliz<strong>at</strong>ion to arbitrary dimensions leads to the following stochastic random<br />

equ<strong>at</strong>ion (SRE):<br />

Xt = AtXt−1 + Bt ; (18)<br />

where (Xt; Bt) are d-dimensional vectors. Each component of Xt can be thought of<br />

as the price of an ass<strong>et</strong> above its fundamental price. The m<strong>at</strong>rices (At) are i<strong>de</strong>ntically<br />

in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt distributed d × d-dimensional stochastic m<strong>at</strong>rices. We assume th<strong>at</strong> Bt are<br />

i<strong>de</strong>ntically in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt distributed random vectors and th<strong>at</strong> (Xt) is a causal st<strong>at</strong>ionary<br />

solution of (18). Generaliz<strong>at</strong>ions introducing additional arbitrary linear terms <strong>at</strong> larger<br />

time lags such as Xt−2;::: can be tre<strong>at</strong>ed with slight modi c<strong>at</strong>ions of our approach<br />

and yield the same conclusions. We shall thus con ne our <strong>de</strong>monstr<strong>at</strong>ion on the SRE<br />

of or<strong>de</strong>r 1, keeping in mind th<strong>at</strong> our results apply analogously to arbitrary or<strong>de</strong>rs of<br />

regressions.<br />

In the following, we <strong>de</strong>note by |·| the Eucli<strong>de</strong>an norm and by · the corresponding<br />

norm for any d × d-m<strong>at</strong>rix A<br />

A =sup|Ax|<br />

: (19)<br />

|x|=1<br />

Technical d<strong>et</strong>ails are given in [32].<br />

3.3. The no-free lunch condition<br />

The valu<strong>at</strong>ion formula (3) and the martingale condition (6) given for a single ass<strong>et</strong><br />

easily extends to a bask<strong>et</strong> of ass<strong>et</strong>s. It is n<strong>at</strong>ural to assume th<strong>at</strong>, for a given period t, the<br />

discount r<strong>at</strong>e rt(i), associ<strong>at</strong>ed with ass<strong>et</strong> i, are all the same. In frictionless mark<strong>et</strong>s, a<br />

<strong>de</strong>vi<strong>at</strong>ion for this hypothesis would lead to arbitrage opportunities. Furthermore, since<br />

the sequence of m<strong>at</strong>rices {At} is assumed to be i.i.d. and therefore st<strong>at</strong>ionary, this<br />

implies th<strong>at</strong> t or rt must be constant and equal, respectively, to and r.<br />

Un<strong>de</strong>r those conditions, we have the following proposition.<br />

Proposition 1. The stochastic process<br />

Xt = AtXt−1 + Bt<br />

s<strong>at</strong>is es the no-arbitrage condition if and only if<br />

(20)<br />

EQ[A]= 1 Id : (21)<br />

The proof is given in Ref. [32] in which this condition (21) is also shown to hold true<br />

un<strong>de</strong>r the historical probability measure P.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!