25.06.2013 Views

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Differenti<strong>at</strong>ing with respect to x1, · · · , xN leads to<br />

where<br />

is the <strong>de</strong>nsity of the copula C.<br />

P (x1, · · · , xn) = ∂F (x1, · · · , xn)<br />

∂x1 · · · ∂xn<br />

= c(F1(x1), · · · , Fn(xn))<br />

c(u1, · · · , uN) = ∂C(u1, · · · , uN)<br />

∂u1 · · · ∂uN<br />

443<br />

N<br />

pi(xi) , (49)<br />

Comparing (50) with (47), the <strong>de</strong>nsity of the copula is given in the present case by<br />

1<br />

c(u1, · · · , uN) = exp<br />

d<strong>et</strong>(V )<br />

<br />

, (51)<br />

i=1<br />

<br />

− 1<br />

2 yt (u) (V −1 − I)y (u)<br />

which is the “Gaussian copula” with covariance m<strong>at</strong>rix V. This result clarifies and justifies the m<strong>et</strong>hod<br />

of (Sorn<strong>et</strong>te <strong>et</strong> al. 2000b) by showing th<strong>at</strong> it essentially amounts to assume arbitrary marginal distributions<br />

with Gaussian copulas. Note th<strong>at</strong> the Gaussian copula results directly from the transform<strong>at</strong>ion to Gaussian<br />

marginals tog<strong>et</strong>her with the choice of maximizing the Shannon entropy un<strong>de</strong>r the constraint of a fixed covariance<br />

m<strong>at</strong>rix. Un<strong>de</strong>r differents constraint, we would have found another maximum entropy copula. This<br />

is not unexpected in analogy with the standard result th<strong>at</strong> the Gaussian law is maximizing the Shannon entropy<br />

<strong>at</strong> fixed given variance. If we were to extend this formul<strong>at</strong>ion by consi<strong>de</strong>ring more general expressions<br />

of the entropy, such th<strong>at</strong> Tsallis entropy (Tsallis 1998), we would have found other copulas.<br />

6.4 Empirical test of the Gaussian copula assumption<br />

We now present some tests of the hypothesis of Gaussian copulas b<strong>et</strong>ween r<strong>et</strong>urns of financial ass<strong>et</strong>s. This<br />

present<strong>at</strong>ion is only for illustr<strong>at</strong>ion purposes, since testing the gaussian copula hypothesis is a <strong>de</strong>lic<strong>at</strong>e task<br />

which has been addressed elsewhere (see (Malevergne and Sorn<strong>et</strong>te 2001)). Here, as an example, we propose<br />

two simple standard m<strong>et</strong>hods.<br />

The first one consists in using the property th<strong>at</strong> Gaussian variables are stable in distribution un<strong>de</strong>r addition.<br />

Thus, a (quantile-quantile or Q − Q) plot of the cumul<strong>at</strong>ive distribution of the sum y1 + · · · + yp versus<br />

the cumul<strong>at</strong>ive Normal distribution with the same estim<strong>at</strong>ed variance should give a straight line in or<strong>de</strong>r to<br />

qualify a multivari<strong>at</strong>e Gaussian distribution (for the transformed y variables). Such tests on empirical d<strong>at</strong>a<br />

are presented in figures 7-9.<br />

The second test amounts to estim<strong>at</strong>ing the covariance m<strong>at</strong>rix V of the sample we consi<strong>de</strong>r. This step is<br />

simple since, for fast <strong>de</strong>caying pdf’s, robust estim<strong>at</strong>ors of the covariance m<strong>at</strong>rix are available. We can then<br />

estim<strong>at</strong>e the distribution of the variable z 2 = y t V −1 y. It is well known th<strong>at</strong> z 2 follows a χ 2 distribution<br />

if y is a Gaussian random vector. Again, the empirical cumul<strong>at</strong>ive distribution of z 2 versus the χ 2 cumul<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

distribution should give a straight line in or<strong>de</strong>r to qualify a multivari<strong>at</strong>e Gaussian distribution (for the<br />

transformed y variables). Such tests on empirical d<strong>at</strong>a are presented in figures 10-12.<br />

First, one can observe th<strong>at</strong> the Gaussian copula hypothesis appears b<strong>et</strong>ter for stocks than for currencies.<br />

As discussed in (Malevergne and Sorn<strong>et</strong>te 2001), this result is quite general. A plausible explan<strong>at</strong>ion lies<br />

in the stronger <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce b<strong>et</strong>ween the currencies compared with th<strong>at</strong> b<strong>et</strong>ween stocks, which is due to<br />

the mon<strong>et</strong>ary policies limiting the fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions b<strong>et</strong>ween the currencies of a group of countries, such as was<br />

the case in the European Mon<strong>et</strong>ary System before the unique Euro currency. Note also th<strong>at</strong> the test of<br />

aggreg<strong>at</strong>ion seems system<strong>at</strong>ically more in favor of the Gaussian copula hypothesis than is the χ 2 test, maybe<br />

due to its smaller sensitivity. Non<strong>et</strong>heless, the very good performance of the Gaussian hypothesis un<strong>de</strong>r the<br />

19<br />

(50)

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!