25.06.2013 Views

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

9.1. Les différentes mesures <strong>de</strong> dépendances extrêmes 247<br />

constraining conditioning. To this aim, we consi<strong>de</strong>r two random variables X and Y and <strong>de</strong>fine their conditional<br />

correl<strong>at</strong>ion coefficient ρA,B, conditioned upon X ∈ A and Y ∈ B, where A and B are two subs<strong>et</strong>s of<br />

R such th<strong>at</strong> Pr{X ∈ A, Y ∈ B} > 0, by<br />

ρA,B =<br />

Cov(X, Y | X ∈ A, Y ∈ B)<br />

Var(X | X ∈ A, Y ∈ B) · Var(Y | X ∈ A, Y ∈ B) . (12)<br />

In this case, it is much more difficult to obtain general results for any specified class of distributions compared<br />

to the previous case of conditioning on a single variable. We have only been able to give the asymptotic<br />

behavior for a Gaussian distribution in the situ<strong>at</strong>ion d<strong>et</strong>ailed below, using the expressions in (Johnson and<br />

Kotz 1972, p 113) or proposition A.1 of (Ang and Chen 2001).<br />

L<strong>et</strong> us assume th<strong>at</strong> the pair of random variables (X,Y) has a Normal distribution with unit unconditional variance<br />

and unconditional correl<strong>at</strong>ion coefficient ρ. The subs<strong>et</strong>s A and B are both choosen equal to [u, +∞),<br />

with u ∈ R+, so th<strong>at</strong> we focus on the correl<strong>at</strong>ion coefficient conditional on the r<strong>et</strong>urns of both X and Y<br />

larger than the threshold u. Denoting by ρu the correl<strong>at</strong>ion coefficient conditional on this particular choice<br />

for the subs<strong>et</strong>s A and B, we are able to show (see eppendix A.2) th<strong>at</strong>, for large u:<br />

ρu ∼u→∞ ρ<br />

1 + ρ<br />

1 − ρ<br />

1<br />

· , (13)<br />

u2 which goes to zero. This <strong>de</strong>cay is faster than in the case governed by (3) resulting from the conditioning on<br />

a single variable leading to ρ + v ∼v→+∞ 1/v, but, unfortun<strong>at</strong>ely, we do not observe a qualit<strong>at</strong>ive change.<br />

Thus, the correl<strong>at</strong>ion coefficient conditioned on both variables does not yield new significant inform<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

and does not provi<strong>de</strong> any special improvement with respect to the correl<strong>at</strong>ion coefficient conditioned on a<br />

single variable.<br />

1.5 Empirical evi<strong>de</strong>nce<br />

We consi<strong>de</strong>r four n<strong>at</strong>ional stock mark<strong>et</strong>s in L<strong>at</strong>in America, namely Argentina (MERVAL in<strong>de</strong>x), Brazil<br />

(IBOV in<strong>de</strong>x), Chile (IPSA in<strong>de</strong>x) and Mexico (MEXBOL in<strong>de</strong>x). We are particularly interested in the<br />

contagion effects which may have occurred across these mark<strong>et</strong>s. We will study this question for the mark<strong>et</strong><br />

in<strong>de</strong>xes expressed in US Dollar to emphasize the effect of the <strong>de</strong>valu<strong>at</strong>ions of local currencies and so to<br />

account for mon<strong>et</strong>ary crises. Doing so, we follow the same m<strong>et</strong>hodology as in most contagion papers (see<br />

(Forbes and Rigobon 2002), for instance). Our sample contains the daily (log) r<strong>et</strong>urns of each stock in<br />

local currency and US dollar during the time interval from January 15, 1992 to June 15, 2002 and thus<br />

encompasses both the Mexican crisis as well as the current Argentina crisis.<br />

Before applying the theor<strong>et</strong>ical results <strong>de</strong>rived above, we first need to check wh<strong>et</strong>her we are allowed to do<br />

so. Namely, we have to test wh<strong>et</strong>her the in<strong>de</strong>x r<strong>et</strong>urns distributions are not too f<strong>at</strong> tailed. In<strong>de</strong>ed, it its well<br />

known th<strong>at</strong> the correl<strong>at</strong>ion coefficient exists if and only if the tail of the distribution <strong>de</strong>cays faster than a<br />

power law with tail in<strong>de</strong>x α = 2, and its estim<strong>at</strong>or given by the Pearson’s coefficient is well behaved if <strong>at</strong><br />

least the fourth moment of the distribution is finite.<br />

Figure 1 represents the complementary distribution of the positive and neg<strong>at</strong>ive tails of the in<strong>de</strong>x r<strong>et</strong>urns in<br />

US dollar. We observe th<strong>at</strong> the positive tail clearly <strong>de</strong>cays faster than a power law with tail in<strong>de</strong>x µ = 2.<br />

In fact, Hill’s estim<strong>at</strong>or provi<strong>de</strong>s a value ranging b<strong>et</strong>ween 3 and 4 for the four in<strong>de</strong>xes. The case of the<br />

neg<strong>at</strong>ive tail is slightly different, particularly for the Brazilian in<strong>de</strong>x. In<strong>de</strong>ed, for the Argentina, the Chilean<br />

and the Mexican in<strong>de</strong>xes, the neg<strong>at</strong>ive tail behaves almost like the positive one, but for the Brazilian in<strong>de</strong>x,<br />

the neg<strong>at</strong>ive tail exponent is hardly larger than two, as confirmed by Hill’s estim<strong>at</strong>or. This means th<strong>at</strong>, in<br />

9

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!