25.06.2013 Views

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

66 3. Distributions exponentielles étirées contre distributions régulièrement variables<br />

1 Motiv<strong>at</strong>ion of the study<br />

The d<strong>et</strong>ermin<strong>at</strong>ion of the precise shape of the tail of the distribution of r<strong>et</strong>urns is a major issue both from<br />

a practical and from an aca<strong>de</strong>mic point of view. For practitioners, it is crucial to accur<strong>at</strong>ely estim<strong>at</strong>e the<br />

low value quantiles of the distribution of r<strong>et</strong>urns (profit and loss) because they are involved in almost all<br />

the mo<strong>de</strong>rn risk management m<strong>et</strong>hods. From an aca<strong>de</strong>mic perspective, many economic and financial theories<br />

rely on a specific param<strong>et</strong>eriz<strong>at</strong>ion of the distributions whose param<strong>et</strong>ers are inten<strong>de</strong>d to represent the<br />

“macroscopic” variables the agents are sensitive to.<br />

The distribution of r<strong>et</strong>urns is one of the most basic characteristics of the mark<strong>et</strong>s and many papers have been<br />

<strong>de</strong>voted to it. Contrarily to the average or expected r<strong>et</strong>urn, for which economic theory provi<strong>de</strong>s gui<strong>de</strong>lines<br />

to assess them in rel<strong>at</strong>ion with risk premium, firm size or book-to-mark<strong>et</strong> equity (see for instance Fama<br />

and French (1996)), the functional form of the distribution of r<strong>et</strong>urns, and especially of extreme r<strong>et</strong>urns, is<br />

much less constrained and still a topic of active <strong>de</strong>b<strong>at</strong>e. Naively, the central limit theorem would lead to<br />

a Gaussian distribution for sufficiently large time intervals over which the r<strong>et</strong>urn is estim<strong>at</strong>ed. Taking the<br />

continuous time limit such th<strong>at</strong> any finite time interval is seen as the sum of an infinite number of increments<br />

thus leads to the paradigm of log-normal distributions of prices and equivalently of Gaussian distributions<br />

of r<strong>et</strong>urns, based on the pioneering work of Bachelier (1900) l<strong>at</strong>er improved by Samuelson (1965). The lognormal<br />

paradigm has been the starting point of many financial theories such as Markovitz (1959)’s portfolio<br />

selection m<strong>et</strong>hod, Sharpe (1964)’s mark<strong>et</strong> equilibrium mo<strong>de</strong>l or Black and Scholes (1973)’s r<strong>at</strong>ional option<br />

pricing theory. However, for real financial d<strong>at</strong>a, the convergence in distribution to a Gaussian law is very<br />

slow (Campbell <strong>et</strong> al. 1997, Bouchaud and Potters 2000, for instance), much slower th<strong>at</strong> predicted for<br />

in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt r<strong>et</strong>urns. As table 1 shows, the excess kurtosis (which is zero for a normal distribution) remains<br />

large even for monthly r<strong>et</strong>urns, testifying of significant <strong>de</strong>vi<strong>at</strong>ions from normality, of the heavy tail behavior<br />

of the distributions of r<strong>et</strong>urns and of significant <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nces b<strong>et</strong>ween r<strong>et</strong>urns (Campbell <strong>et</strong> al. 1997).<br />

Another i<strong>de</strong>a rooted in economic theory consists in invoking the “Gibr<strong>at</strong> principle” (Simon 1957) initially<br />

used to account for the growth of cities and of wealth through a mechanism combining stochastic multiplic<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

and additive noises (Levy <strong>et</strong> al. 1996, Sorn<strong>et</strong>te and Cont 1997, Biham <strong>et</strong> al 1998, Sorn<strong>et</strong>te 1998)<br />

leading to a Par<strong>et</strong>o distribution of sizes (Champenowne 1953, Gabaix 1999). R<strong>at</strong>ional bubble mo<strong>de</strong>ls a<br />

la Blanchard and W<strong>at</strong>son (1982) can also be cast in this m<strong>at</strong>hem<strong>at</strong>ical framework of stochastic recurrence<br />

equ<strong>at</strong>ions and leads to distribution with power law tails, albeit with a strong constraint on the tail exponent<br />

(Lux and Sorn<strong>et</strong>te 2002, Malevergne and Sorn<strong>et</strong>te 2001). These frameworks suggest th<strong>at</strong> an altern<strong>at</strong>ive and<br />

n<strong>at</strong>ural way to capture the heavy tail character of the distributions of r<strong>et</strong>urns is to use distributions with<br />

power-like tails (Par<strong>et</strong>o, Generalized Par<strong>et</strong>o, stable laws) or more generally, regularly-varying distributions<br />

(Bingham <strong>et</strong> al 1987) 1 , the l<strong>at</strong>er encompassing all the former.<br />

In the early 1960s, Man<strong>de</strong>lbrot (1963) and Fama (1965) presented evi<strong>de</strong>nce th<strong>at</strong> distributions of r<strong>et</strong>urns can<br />

be well approxim<strong>at</strong>ed by a symm<strong>et</strong>ric Levy stable law with tail in<strong>de</strong>x b about 1.7. These estim<strong>at</strong>es of the<br />

power tail in<strong>de</strong>x have recently been confirmed by Mittnik <strong>et</strong> al. (1998), and slightly different indices of the<br />

stable law (b = 1.4) were suggested by Mantegna and Stanley (1995, 2000).<br />

On the other hand, there are numerous evi<strong>de</strong>nces of a larger value of the tail in<strong>de</strong>x b ∼ = 3 (Longin 1996,<br />

Guillaume <strong>et</strong> al. 1997, Gopikrishnan <strong>et</strong> al. 1998, Müller <strong>et</strong> al. 1998, Farmer 1999, Lux 2000). See also the<br />

various altern<strong>at</strong>ive param<strong>et</strong>eriz<strong>at</strong>ions in term of the Stu<strong>de</strong>nt distribution (Bl<strong>at</strong>tberg and Gonne<strong>de</strong>s 1974, Kon<br />

1984), hyperbolic distributions (Eberlein <strong>et</strong> al. 1998, Prause 1998), normal inverse Gaussian distributions<br />

(Barndorff-Nielsen 1997), and Pearson type-VII distributions (Nagahara and Kitagawa 1999), which all have<br />

an asymptotic power law tail and are regularly varying. Thus, a general conclusion of this group of authors<br />

1 The general represent<strong>at</strong>ion of a regularly varying distribution is given by ¯F(x) = L(x) · x −α , where L(·) is a slowly varying<br />

function, th<strong>at</strong> is, limx→∞L(tx)/L(x) = 1 for any finite t.<br />

2

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!