25.06.2013 Views

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

432 14. Gestion <strong>de</strong> Portefeuilles multimoments <strong>et</strong> équilibre <strong>de</strong> marché<br />

3 The generalized efficient frontier and some of its properties<br />

We now address the problem of the portfolio selection and optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion, based on the risk measures introduced<br />

in the previous section. As we have already seen, there is a large choice of relevant risk measures<br />

from which the portfolio manager is free to choose as a function of his own aversion to small versus large<br />

risks. A strong risk aversion to large risks will lead him to choose a risk measure which puts the emphasis<br />

on the large fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions. The simplest examples of such risk measures are provi<strong>de</strong>d by the high-or<strong>de</strong>r centered<br />

moments or cumulants. Obviously, the utility function of the fund manager plays a central role in his<br />

choice of the risk measure. The rel<strong>at</strong>ion b<strong>et</strong>ween the central moments and the utility function has already<br />

been un<strong>de</strong>rlined by several authors such as (Rubinstein 1973) or (Jurczenko and Maill<strong>et</strong> 2002), who have<br />

shown th<strong>at</strong> an economic agent with a quartic utility function is n<strong>at</strong>urally sensitive to the first four moments<br />

of his expected wealth distribution. But, as stressed before, we do not wish to consi<strong>de</strong>r the expected utility<br />

formalism since our goal, in this paper, is not to study the un<strong>de</strong>rlying behavior leading to the choice of any<br />

risk measure.<br />

The choice of the risk measure also <strong>de</strong>pends upon the time horizon of investment. In<strong>de</strong>ed, as the time<br />

scale increases, the distribution of ass<strong>et</strong> r<strong>et</strong>urns progressively converges to the Gaussian pdf, so th<strong>at</strong> only<br />

the variance remains relevant for very long term investment horizons. However, for shorter time horizons,<br />

say, for portfolio rebalanced <strong>at</strong> a weekly, daily or intra-day time scales, choosing a risk measure putting the<br />

emphasis on the large fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions, such as the centered moments µ6 or µ8 or the cumulants C6 or C8 (or of<br />

larger or<strong>de</strong>rs), may be necessary to account for the “wild” price fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions usually observed for such short<br />

time scales.<br />

Our present approach uses a single time scale over which the r<strong>et</strong>urns are estim<strong>at</strong>ed, and is thus restricted<br />

to portfolio selection with a fixed investment horizon. Extensions to a portofolio analysis and optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

in terms of high-or<strong>de</strong>r moments and cumulants performed simultaneously over different time scales can be<br />

found in (Muzy <strong>et</strong> al. 2001).<br />

3.1 Efficient frontier without risk-free ass<strong>et</strong><br />

L<strong>et</strong> us consi<strong>de</strong>r N risky ass<strong>et</strong>s, <strong>de</strong>noted by X1, · · · , XN. Our goal is to find the best possible alloc<strong>at</strong>ion, given<br />

a s<strong>et</strong> of constraints.The portfolio optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion generalizing the approach of (Sorn<strong>et</strong>te <strong>et</strong> al. 2000a, An<strong>de</strong>rsen<br />

and Sorn<strong>et</strong>te 2001) corresponds to accounting for large fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions of the ass<strong>et</strong>s through the risk measures<br />

introduced above in the presence of a constraint on the r<strong>et</strong>urn as well as the “no-short sells” constraint:<br />

⎧<br />

⎪⎨<br />

⎪⎩<br />

inf wi∈[0,1] ρα({wi})<br />

<br />

i≥1 wi = 1<br />

<br />

i≥1 wiµ(i) = µ ,<br />

wi ≥ 0, ∀i > 0,<br />

where wi is the weight of Xi and µ(i) its expected r<strong>et</strong>urn. In all the sequel, the subscript α in ρα will refer<br />

to the <strong>de</strong>gree of homogeneity of the risk measure.<br />

This problem cannot be solved analytically (except in the Markovitz’s case where the risk measure is given<br />

by the variance). We need to perform numerical calcul<strong>at</strong>ions to obtain the shape of the efficient frontier.<br />

Non<strong>et</strong>heless, when the ρα’s <strong>de</strong>notes the centered moments or any convex risk measure, we can assert th<strong>at</strong><br />

this optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion problem is a convex optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion problem and th<strong>at</strong> it admits one and only one solution<br />

which can be easily d<strong>et</strong>ermined by standard numerical relax<strong>at</strong>ion or gradient m<strong>et</strong>hods.<br />

As an example, we have represented In figure 2, the mean-ρα efficient frontier for a portfolio ma<strong>de</strong> of seventeen<br />

ass<strong>et</strong>s (see appendix A for d<strong>et</strong>ails) in the plane (µ, ρ 1/α<br />

α ), where ρα represents the centered moments<br />

8<br />

(13)

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!