25.06.2013 Views

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

312 9. Mesure <strong>de</strong> la dépendance extrême entre <strong>de</strong>ux actifs financiers<br />

them, but in every case, we found th<strong>at</strong> the relevant range for the tail in<strong>de</strong>x estim<strong>at</strong>ion was b<strong>et</strong>ween<br />

the 1% and 5% quantiles. Tables 3 and 4 give the estim<strong>at</strong>ed tail in<strong>de</strong>x for each ass<strong>et</strong> and residues<br />

<strong>at</strong> the 1%, 2.5% and 5% quantile, for both the positive and the neg<strong>at</strong>ive tails for the two time<br />

sub-intervals. The second time interval from January 1980 to December 2000 is characterized by<br />

values of the tail in<strong>de</strong>xes th<strong>at</strong> are homogeneous over the various quantiles and range b<strong>et</strong>ween 3 and<br />

4 for the neg<strong>at</strong>ive tails and b<strong>et</strong>ween 3 and 5 for the positive tails. There is slightly more dispersions<br />

in the first time interval from July 1962 to December 1979.<br />

For each ass<strong>et</strong> and their residue of the regression on the mark<strong>et</strong> factor, we tested wh<strong>et</strong>her the<br />

hypothesis, according to which the tail in<strong>de</strong>x measured for each ass<strong>et</strong> and each residue is the same<br />

as the tail in<strong>de</strong>x of the Standard & Poor’s 500 in<strong>de</strong>x, can be rejected <strong>at</strong> the 95% confi<strong>de</strong>nce level,<br />

for a given quantile. Before proceding with the present<strong>at</strong>ion of our tests, two cave<strong>at</strong>s have to<br />

be accounted for. First, due to the phenomenon of vol<strong>at</strong>ility clustering in financial time series,<br />

extremes are more likely to occur tog<strong>et</strong>her. In this situ<strong>at</strong>ion, Hill’s estim<strong>at</strong>or is no more normally<br />

distributed with variance α 2 /k. In fact, for weakly <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt time series, it can only be asserted<br />

th<strong>at</strong> the estim<strong>at</strong>or remains consistent (see Rootzén and <strong>de</strong> Haan (1998)). Moreover, as shown by<br />

Kearns and Pagan (1997) for h<strong>et</strong>eroskedastic time series, the variance of the estim<strong>at</strong>ed tail in<strong>de</strong>x<br />

can be seven times larger than the variance given by the asymptic normality assumption. Second,<br />

the idiosyncr<strong>at</strong>ic noise is estim<strong>at</strong>ed by substracting β times the factor from the ass<strong>et</strong> r<strong>et</strong>urn. Thus,<br />

even when the factor and the error-term are in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt, the empirically estim<strong>at</strong>ed residues <strong>de</strong>pend<br />

on the realiz<strong>at</strong>ions of the factor. As a consequence, the tail in<strong>de</strong>x estim<strong>at</strong>ors for the factor and for<br />

the idiosyncr<strong>at</strong>ic noise are correl<strong>at</strong>ed. This correl<strong>at</strong>ion obviously <strong>de</strong>pends on the exact form of the<br />

distributions of the factor and the indiosyncr<strong>at</strong>ic noise. Even without the knowledge of the true<br />

test st<strong>at</strong>istics, for both problem<strong>at</strong>ic points, we can assert th<strong>at</strong> the fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions of the estim<strong>at</strong>ors<br />

are larger than those given by the asymptotically normal st<strong>at</strong>isics for i.i.d realiz<strong>at</strong>ions. Thus,<br />

performing the test un<strong>de</strong>r the asymptotic normality assumption is more constraining than un<strong>de</strong>r<br />

the true (but unknown) test st<strong>at</strong>istics, so th<strong>at</strong> the non-rejection of the equality hypothesis un<strong>de</strong>r<br />

the assumption of a normally distributed estim<strong>at</strong>or ensures th<strong>at</strong> we would not be able to reject this<br />

hypothesis un<strong>de</strong>r the real st<strong>at</strong>istics of the estim<strong>at</strong>or.<br />

The values which reject the equality hypothesis are indic<strong>at</strong>ed by a star in the tables 3 and 4. During<br />

the second time interval from January 1980 to December 2000, only four residues have a tail in<strong>de</strong>x<br />

significantly different from th<strong>at</strong> of th<strong>at</strong> Standard & Poor’s 500, and only in the neg<strong>at</strong>ive tail. The<br />

situ<strong>at</strong>ion is not as good during the first time interval, especially for the neg<strong>at</strong>ive tail, for which<br />

no less than 13 ass<strong>et</strong>s and 10 residues out of 20 have a tail in<strong>de</strong>x significantly different from the<br />

Standard & Poor’s 500 ones, for the 5% quantile. Recall th<strong>at</strong> the the equality tests have been<br />

performed un<strong>de</strong>r the assumption of a normally distributed estim<strong>at</strong>or with variance α 2 /k which, as<br />

explained above, is too strong an hypothesis. As a consequence, a rejection un<strong>de</strong>r the normality<br />

hypothesis does not imply necessarily th<strong>at</strong> the equality hypothesis would have been rejected un<strong>de</strong>r<br />

the true st<strong>at</strong>istics. While providing a note of caution, this st<strong>at</strong>ement is nevertheless not very useful<br />

from a practical point of view. More importantly, we stress th<strong>at</strong> the equality of the tail indices of<br />

the distribution of the factor and of the idiosyncr<strong>at</strong>ic noise is not crucial. In<strong>de</strong>ed, we shall propose<br />

below two different estim<strong>at</strong>ors for the coefficient of tail <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce. One of them does not rely on<br />

the equality of these two tail indices and thus remains oper<strong>at</strong>ional even when they are different<br />

and in particular when the tail in<strong>de</strong>x of the idiosyncr<strong>at</strong>ic noise appears larger than the tail of the<br />

factor.<br />

To summarize, our tests confirm th<strong>at</strong> the tail in<strong>de</strong>xes of most stock r<strong>et</strong>urn distributions range<br />

b<strong>et</strong>ween three and four, even though no b<strong>et</strong>ter precision can be given with good significance.<br />

Moreover, in most cases, we can assume th<strong>at</strong> both the ass<strong>et</strong>, the factor and the residue have the<br />

13

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!