25.06.2013 Views

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

statistique, théorie et gestion de portefeuille - Docs at ISFA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

9.2. Estim<strong>at</strong>ion du coefficient <strong>de</strong> dépendance <strong>de</strong> queue 307<br />

to zero. This non-intuitive result stems from the fact th<strong>at</strong> the tail <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce is quantifying not<br />

just a <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce but a specific <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce for extreme co-movements. Thus, in or<strong>de</strong>r to g<strong>et</strong><br />

a non-vanishing tail-<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce, the fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions of the factor must be ‘wild’ enough, which is<br />

not realized with rapidly varying distributions, irrespective of the rel<strong>at</strong>ive values of the standard<br />

<strong>de</strong>vi<strong>at</strong>ions of the factor and the idosyncr<strong>at</strong>ic noise.<br />

2.3 Coefficient of tail <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce for regularly varying factors<br />

2.3.1 Example of the factor mo<strong>de</strong>l with Stu<strong>de</strong>nt distribution<br />

In or<strong>de</strong>r to account for the power-law tail behavior observed for the distributions of ass<strong>et</strong>s r<strong>et</strong>urns<br />

it is logical to consi<strong>de</strong>r th<strong>at</strong> the factor and the indiosyncr<strong>at</strong>ic noise also have power-law tailed<br />

distributions. As an illustr<strong>at</strong>ion, we will assume th<strong>at</strong> Y and ε are distributed according to a<br />

Stu<strong>de</strong>nt’s distribution with the same number of <strong>de</strong>grees of freedom ν (and thus same tail exponent<br />

ν). L<strong>et</strong> us <strong>de</strong>note by σ the scale factor of the distribution of ε while the scale factor of the<br />

distribution of Y is chosen equal to one 3 . Applying the theorem previously established, we find<br />

th<strong>at</strong> f(x) = ν/x ν+1 and l = β<br />

<br />

1 +<br />

σ<br />

β<br />

1<br />

λ± =<br />

1 +<br />

ν 1/ν<br />

, so th<strong>at</strong> the coefficient of tail <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce is<br />

σ<br />

β<br />

ν , and β > 0. (10)<br />

As expected, the tail <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce increases as β increases and as σ <strong>de</strong>creases. Since the idiosyncr<strong>at</strong>ic<br />

vol<strong>at</strong>ility of the ass<strong>et</strong> increases when the scale factor σ increases, this results simply means th<strong>at</strong><br />

the tail <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce <strong>de</strong>creases when the idiosyncr<strong>at</strong>ic vol<strong>at</strong>ility of a stock increases rel<strong>at</strong>ive to the<br />

mark<strong>et</strong> vol<strong>at</strong>ility. The <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce with respect to ν is less intuitive. In particular, l<strong>et</strong> ν go to<br />

infinity. Then, λ → 0 if σ > β and λ → 1 for σ < β. This is surprising as one could argue th<strong>at</strong>, as<br />

ν → ∞, the Stu<strong>de</strong>nt distribution tends to the Gaussian law. As a consequence, one would expect<br />

the same coefficient of <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce λ± = 0 as for rapidly varying functions. The reason for the<br />

non-certain convergence of λ± to zero as ν → ∞ is rooted in a subtle non-commut<strong>at</strong>ivity (and<br />

non-uniform convergence) of the two limits ν → ∞ and u → 1. In<strong>de</strong>ed, when taking first the limit<br />

u → 1, the result λ → 1 for β > σ indic<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> a sufficiently strong factor coefficient β always<br />

ensures the validity of the power law regime, wh<strong>at</strong>ever the value of ν. Correl<strong>at</strong>ively, in this regime<br />

β > σ, λ± is an increasing function of ν.<br />

The result (10) is of interest for financial economics purpose because it provi<strong>de</strong>s a simple param<strong>et</strong>ric<br />

illustr<strong>at</strong>ion and interpr<strong>et</strong><strong>at</strong>ion of how the risk of large co-movements is affected by the three key<br />

param<strong>et</strong>ers entering in the <strong>de</strong>finition of the factor mo<strong>de</strong>l. It allows one to weight how the ingredients<br />

of the factor mo<strong>de</strong>l impact on the large risks captured by λ± and thus links the financial basis<br />

un<strong>de</strong>rlying the factor mo<strong>de</strong>l to the extreme multivari<strong>at</strong>e risks.<br />

2.3.2 General result<br />

We now provi<strong>de</strong> the general result valid for any regularly varying distribution. L<strong>et</strong> the factor<br />

Y follows a regularly varying distribution with tail in<strong>de</strong>x α: in other words, the complementary<br />

cumul<strong>at</strong>ive distribution of Y is such th<strong>at</strong> ¯ FY (y) = L(y) · y −α , where L(y) is a slowly varying<br />

3 Such a choice is always possible via a rescaling of the coefficient β.<br />

8

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!